By Amity
Shlaes
Monday,
July 23, 2023
Americans freeze
like deer in the headlights when our leaders confront them with fancy economic
plans.
For
example, Treasury secretary Janet Yellen has begun campaigning for a new
experiment, what she calls “modern supply-side economics.” Such terminology disorients
plenty of observers, who until the Treasury secretary spoke were accustomed to
hearing Democratic administration officials utter “supply-side” only as a
pejorative.
Supply-side
was Ronald Reagan’s doctrine, expressed in two simple policies: A further
surprise came when Secretary Yellen seemed to be expanding Reagan’s defined
theory into a sort of massive omnibus. According to the secretary, supply-side
policy should include everything from reducing carbon emissions to universal
prekindergarten.
“It is
strategy that is pro-growth but inclusive and green,” Yellen told
Yale University president Peter Salovey this past spring.
Inclusive
and green, indeed, but not supply-side. A second’s sober thought would make
clear that green spending projects, green regulation, and pre-K support all
undermine the old supply-side principle. If you write policy that favors one
company over another — the industrial policy embedded in Yellen’s argument —
you reduce overall productivity of companies (the supply side). If you tighten
regulations and spend further billions on projects such as universal pre-K, you
distract the supply side (business), destabilize money, and preclude lower tax
rates. But deer don’t think when they spot the omnibus roaring toward them.
They just wait for the inevitable.
How much
damage broad new economic theories can wreak becomes clear in evidence from
America’s past. Before the 1970s, there was an economic law most Americans
believed, mainly because economists, especially Democratic economists, told
them to. An economy could suffer from either inflation or unemployment, but not
both. That tradeoff was part of a series of doctrines inspired by Democrats’
favorite economist, John Maynard Keynes. Then President Richard Nixon pulled a
Yellen, blithely informing a network moderator that he was now “a Keynesian in
economics,” and was introducing what he grandly called the New Economic Policy.
Since
Nixon was a Republican, Americans were befuddled. Weren’t Republicans supposed
to be for markets, at least some of the time? The title “New Economic Policy”
disconcerted the public further, similar as it was to the original New Economic
Policy, Lenin’s cynical 1921 scheme to allow certain capitalist freedoms in his
empire until that empire became a pure collectivist paradise. The similarity
between the names shamed Nixon advisers into dropping the NEP title, but not
into dropping the project. Nixon dazzled the public yet further with large
spending programs, random efforts to prop up or push down the dollar, and price
controls, the last a policy Keynes himself had explicitly rejected.
A half a
century earlier, Keynes had written that the “presumption
of a spurious value for the currency, by the force of law expressed in the
regulation of price, contains in itself . . . the seeds of final economic
decay.”
Decay
was indeed what we got in the 1970s.
Before
citizens’ heads could clear, Nixon’s “Keynesian” policy brought both
unemployment and inflation. And, to describe an impossibility that was now
reality, yet another economic mystery term: stagflation.
Far
worse than the 1970s was that era when economic theorists dominated the most,
the 1930s. A violent market crash and heavy unemployment handed a license to
Franklin Roosevelt’s Brains Trust — and they ran with it. The Brains Trust, a
group including a number of social scientists, informed Americans it was time
to test all kinds of new theories: that larger companies if promoted through
federal policy could lead the economy in recovery, that consumer choice in
product slowed recovery, and that low prices hurt recovery. All these
principles were duly incorporated in the application of the 1933 law that was
the centerpiece of the New Deal, the National Industrial Recovery Act.
When
even the Brookings Institution allowed that this Recovery Act was impeding
recovery, the Roosevelt administration merely shifted philosophy. In the mid
1930s, fresh official doctrine held that radical labor unions and class war
against the rich would bring recovery; in the late 1930s, vigorous antitrust
prosecution of large companies was sold as best medicine and the order of the
day. Operating on another weird principle, that wealth inequality impedes
recovery, the administration also hauled as many business leaders into court
for tax violations as it could manage, prosecuting the star of the 1920s,
former Treasury secretary Andrew Mellon, for years. These antidotes failed as
well, and one in ten workers was still jobless eight years into what was
becoming known as the Great Depression.
Two
economic eminences who did concede the tragedy in plain English were Keynes and
Benjamin Anderson. Keynes warned that the Roosevelt administration’s assault on
utilities, one of its more brutal, would not restore the economy. It would be
less damaging to nationalize utilities outright, which was Keynes’s own
preference, or to simply leave the utilities alone. But what, asked Keynes, was
the use of “chasing the utilities around the lot every other week?”
The
vacillating Roosevelt’s preferred mode, experimentation, was itself doing
damage. Anderson, of Chase Bank, blamed the initial downturn on the
economist-led government’s decision to “play God.” The duration of the Depression
Anderson also attributed to a government that, rather than recognizing its own
failures and “retiring from the role of God,” merely determined that it must
“play God yet more vigorously.”
It is no
accident that Anderson dropped economics and turned to another lexicon to
express the tragedy that was the Depression. In fact, as I found when I pulled
together an anthology of critics of the New Deal,
some of the Depression’s best explainers were, like Keynes, foreigners or,
failing that, foreigners to the economics profession.
One of
my favorites is Odette Keun, a Dutch journalist who had studied planning in the
land of planning, Soviet Russia. In the mid 1930s, Keun came to our shores to
inspect the revolution that was the New Deal and, especially, the license for
class war the administration’s policy of supporting unions had given union
leaders.
Keun
indeed found that “certain spots, notably the enormous industrial and shipping
areas, are in violent social convulsions.” But these were only certain spots.
Whatever the feisty John L. Lewis of the United Mine Workers claimed, and
however the New Dealers nudged, the individual American worker had little
appetite for revolution.
“Broadly
speaking,” wrote the honest Keun, “labor in America is conservative. It is one
of the most flabbergasting discoveries I have made.” What mattered to Americans
— and to their economy’s future — was that the average worker “clung with
intense persistence to the traditional hope of escaping one day — soon — from
the ranks of the employee into the ranks of the small entrepreneur, where he
would be hampered by the social legislation that would have benefited him as a
simple worker.”
Yet
blunter was Rose Wilder Lane, the daughter of the author who captured the
spirit of the prairie in her Little House series, Laura
Ingalls Wilder. Lane suggested in the Saturday Evening Post that
the government was crafting data to make matters look darker than they were,
and to make an impermanent downturn seem permanent.
“We look
too much at charts and figures.” Lane said. Lane lived near a village of 800
people, rated by New Deal authorities “a submarginal farming community
technically known as rural slums in the Ozarks. Not sixty persons in this town
would appear in statistics above the ‘line of subsistence.’” Nonetheless the
people in the village had telephones, radios, automobiles, and even washing
machines, all items that had been rarities just 15 years earlier.
“The
spirit of individualism is still here,” Lane, slightly grim, noted in 1936,
even though New Deal “relief rolls” and “checks from public funds” were
challenging that spirit. Around then, Friedrich von Hayek was still thinking
over his notion of spontaneous order in London. Yet without higher education,
and absent acquaintance with Hayek, Lane captured the Hayekian phenomenon:
man’s “certain instinct of orderliness and of self-preservation which enables
multitudes of free human beings to get together.”
There
was another analyst who could claim even less formal education than Lane:
Isabel Paterson, a book reviewer at the Herald Tribune. Paterson,
who had attended school for three years, and in a Canadian country school at
that, focused on individual productivity, though she called it “energy.”
All
progress for workers was based on the individual; “labor legislation,” a key
part of the New Deal, was “worse than useless. No law can give power to private
persons; every law transfers power from private persons to government.” (Had
Paterson lived in the 1990s, she would have seen through conservative economic
chatter as well as through progressive jargon, and understood the inherit
contradiction in the Reagan-Bush-era slogan of “empowerment.”) Known in her set
as the Goddess of Common Sense, Paterson put the New Deal in its place by
gazing past it. That more Americans could not see this infuriated Ayn Rand, who
gave Paterson’s ideas life in her novels. “Pat is an example of the penalizing
of ability. The conservatives actually reject her for being too good,” wrote
Rand in her journal.
Perhaps
the most insightful of all the period’s self-taught critics, the columnist
Garet Garrett, assailed planners’ pragmatism itself. Garrett refused to speak
in economic terms, or to rate policy by what worked, or what didn’t.
After
all, the New Deal worked, in some narrow political way, when it provided a
temporary job laying brick to an unemployed apprentice. The launch of Sputnik
would “work” for Nikita Khrushchev in the sense that it suggested to the people
of the Soviet Union that the Soviet system was capable of competing with the
United States in the space race. Yet later, doping weightlifters or swimmers
“worked” for the Honecker regime in East Germany, in that it secured the regime
prestigious medals in international competitions. As Garrett noted, to
challenge New Deal economists in their own language was to doom oneself to
defeat. “It’s no use saying this or that won’t work, or won’t work here.
Many things that we hate may work.”
The
point of all these outsiders was a simple one, with relevance for today.
Economics has its uses. But economics, however vast, cannot do all that is
necessary for the human soul. Indeed: the broader the economic plan, the more
dazzling its name, the more suspect.
What
matters, more than markets even, is the individual, the basis for the rest.
People are not lab rats. Nor must they freeze like deer. If today, to
paraphrase Rose Wilder Lane, “the spirit of individualism is still here,” then
individuals, given a chance, can be relied upon to build and thrive. Call
this theory anything you like. Just not economics.
No comments:
Post a Comment