By Kevin D. Williamson
Wednesday, August 21, 2024
A few years ago, Kate McKinnon had a pretty good skit on Saturday
Night Live called “What
Still Works?” in which she “interviewed” a parade of horribles—Marjorie
Taylor Greene, a meme-stock investor, etc.—in a quest to figure out what, if
anything, still works. At one point, she spoke with Jack Dorsey (played by
Mikey Day), then the boss of what was then called Twitter:
Jack Dorsey: While we’re gathering
opinions on what works, would you say that my chin-beard is working?
Kate McKinnon: It’s working in
terms of keeping me a lesbian.
Good skit. Good question, too.
If I were designing the U.S. government from the ground
up, my hard little libertarian heart would not have wanted to include many
things we currently have, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and
the Federal Reserve among them. I opposed the bailouts of the financial sector
in 2008 and still oppose similar programs.
But the question “What still works?” raises another
important question—often the most important question: “Compared to what?” And
one of the lessons of the 2008-09 financial crisis was that the FDIC and the
Federal Reserve and lots of other similar institutions—imperfect though they
may be and philosophically vexatious as their existence is—work pretty well. We
could have done a lot worse in those years than we did, and we could have done
a lot worse during and after the COVID-19 pandemic than we did. Our European
cousins are not fools and miscreants, but they’ve struggled
more with inflation than we have in recent years, thanks in part to their
self-imposed vulnerability to energy shocks.
A couple of weeks ago, my friend David French caused a
ruckus by writing the least surprising column he has written during his time at
the New York Times, in which he stated that he intended to vote for
Kamala Harris in order “to try to save conservatism.” While there were some
thoughtful responses, for the most part, the right harrumphed
as one, with critics demanding to know: What good thing, from a conservative
point of view, could possibly come from a vote for Kamala Harris? If we set
aside the fact that this election is unlikely to provide the Republican Party
with what it really needs most—a humiliating 48-state landslide defeat, which
is what it is going to take to sober up these miscreants—we might find the
answer in a few boring things, including allowing the Fed to continue to be one
of those things that work pretty well.
If by “conservative” you mean “ideologically rightist” or
“doing things that bring power to politicians who belong to the Republican
Party,” then you surely understand and endorse Donald Trump’s recent remarks
(which he is, of course, already
backing away from) that as president he should have more control over Fed
policy because—and let’s go ahead and quote
the dolt to get the full dose of intellectual rigor on display here—“I made
a lot of money. I was very successful. And I think I have a better instinct
than, in many cases, people that would be on the Federal Reserve, or the
chairman.” So, there’s that.
If, on the other hand, you take “conservative” to mean … conservative
… then Kamala Harris’ stated policy preference (offered here with the caveat
that you have to check her positions every 20 minutes to see which of Trump’s she
has taken up) is the more conservative option, i.e., the
tried-and-true conservative policy of leaving well enough alone. “The Fed is an
independent entity,” she said
recently. “As president, I would never interfere in the decisions that the
Fed makes.”
Who knows whether she means it. But whatever degree of
sincerity we assign to her statement, Harris’ hands-off attitude toward the
Fed’s independence is surely more conservative than Trump’s instinctive
approach, which is: “Give me power over that thing because I want it and damn
it I’m still rich from reality shows and scam colleges in spite of being an
utterly incompetent real-estate investor!”
If you want to change things at the Fed—and, though I am
inclined to leave well enough alone for the moment, there is much that needs
reforming in the central bank—Trump’s instinct to politicize it and put it
under presidential authority is precisely the wrong way to go. As Dominic
Pino put it at National Review: “Independent monetary policy is
better than politician-controlled monetary policy. Rules-based monetary policy
is better than independent monetary policy.”
That is … probably right. If you want a more
predictable monetary policy and a policymaking environment with less discretion
in it, then a rules-based approach would be a big improvement. Of course, one
would want to preserve some discretion in extremis, which raises the question
of who has discretion about invoking that discretion, which puts us into a
recursive loop that ends with reiterating our confession that man is a fallen
creature, crooked timber out of which no straight monetary policy may be made,
etc. But we don’t have to take it back that far.
What would a rules-based system look like? There are two
main models for that.
One is adopting a “Taylor rule,” which has the reassuring
quality of having some math in it. Not that the rule’s namesake, John B.
Taylor, thinks that policymakers were going to break out the slide rules: “If
there is anything about which modern macroeconomics is clear however—and on
which there is substantial consensus—it is that policy rules have major
advantages over discretion in improving economic performance,” he wrote in his noted
1993 paper on the subject. “Hence, it is important to preserve the concept
of a policy rule even in an environment where it is practically impossible to
follow mechanically the algebraic formulas economists write down to describe
their preferred policy rules.” Taylor offers up some algebra and—bear in mind
that he was writing in the early 1990s—observed: “What is perhaps surprising is
that this rule fits the actual policy performance during the last few years
remarkably well.” The fact that there is no rule saying that the Fed must
follow a rule doesn’t mean that the Fed is, in fact, operating willy-nilly.
Taylor rules (there are a few variations) focus on the difference between
the desired inflation rate and the observed inflation rate, which has been the
effective convention among competent modern central bankers for a long time.
But there are challenges: You have to measure a lot of variables with a high
degree of accuracy to follow a Taylor rule rigorously and effectively.
That is one big argument for the major alternative to a
Taylor rule, which goes by the name “nominal GDP targeting,” a policy eloquently
championed by Ramesh Ponnuru, among others. Nominal GDP targeting adjusts
policy in response to a single variable: the overall level of spending in the
economy. Nominal GDP can go up for two reasons: 1. because of economic growth;
2. because of inflation. (Likewise, it can decline because of economic
contraction or deflation.) To simplify (a lot!), this model holds that whether
nominal GDP is growing doesn’t really matter because of real economic expansion
or because of inflation or—as almost always is the case—because of some mix of the
two. If the economy is growing very quickly, then you want higher interest
rates to keep it from growing so fast that it produces inflation; if it is
growing because of inflation, then you want higher interest rates to drive that
inflation down. As David Beckworth and Joshua R. Hendrickson of the Mercatus
Center argued in
a 2016 paper: “Unlike a Taylor rule, which requires knowledge of inflation,
actual output, and potential output, a nominal GDP target requires knowledge
only of overall spending.”
Whichever version of rules-based monetary policy tickles
your philosophical fancy, the goals are the same: We want a monetary policy
that encourages growth and all the good things that come from growth
(employment, higher wages, wealthier families, etc.) while also ensuring a
reasonable level of stability in prices. We want monetary authorities—whether
they are made of flesh and blood and pinstripes or mostly made of algebra—that
achieve this in a way that is predictable, because we have enough drama and chaos
in our public life as it is. Not much of that argues for giving more
monetary-policy power to the president, and none of it argues for giving
any monetary-policy power to Donald Trump.
Marcus Aurelius advises leaders against worrying too much
what future generations will say about them. (He is known to readers as a Stoic
philosopher, but bear in mind that his day job was emperor.) Look around
you! he wrote. (I am paraphrasing.) You don’t place much value on the
good opinion of the men of your own generation, and what makes you think that
the judgment of future generations will be any more worth caring about? I
do not think very much of Donald Trump—in case you hadn’t
noticed—but I do not think that future presidents are any less likely
to be dim, fickle, mercurial, cowardly, or enslaved by their passions. For that
reason, if for no other, the prospect of giving presidents or other elected
officers more power over monetary policy rather than leaving that power
invested in an independent central bank seems to me a terrible idea. There is a
lot of talk just now about “threats to democracy,” and I share some of those
concerns, but there are places where we need less democracy, too, and
monetary policy is one of them.
If it should come to pass that the discretion of our
central bankers ends up costing us more than it is worth, then we have a few
options for imposing rules-based constraints on them. Some critics argue that
we have already reached that point, and some of them make a pretty good case.
But I am not yet convinced of the wisdom of destabilizing things today in a
quest for greater stability tomorrow. If Kamala Harris really wants to leave
well enough alone and let the Fed do its job, then she has stumbled onto the
right policy, which also happens to be the conservative one.
No comments:
Post a Comment