By Kevin D. Williamson
Tuesday, September 22, 2015
Donald Trump has promised that he will ease burdens on
the middle class by going after “the hedge-fund guys,” who, he believes, do not
pay enough in taxes. “They’re making a tremendous amount of money — they have
to pay taxes,” he says. Because the one thing in which Trump is consistent is
his vagueness, it is not 100 percent clear whether what he is talking about is
the so-called carried-interest loophole, which is very much on the minds of
people with economic-policy views similar to Trump’s — meaning Bernie Sanders
and Hillary Rodham Clinton and other cookie-cutter progressives — but in any
case, it is worth having a look at the reality and the myths of how hedge funds
and other financial firms are taxed, assuming that we want to start with facts
and proceed to opinion rather than go like a crab backward.
The myth is this: Hedge-fund managers take home
tremendous paychecks that are really plain old payments for services but which
are disguised as long-term capital gains, meaning that they get taxed at 15
percent rather than the 39.6 percent I pay on my salary, which is fundamentally
unfair.
The thing about myths is, they’re myths.
If you will forgive a brief little dip into finance
gobbledygook, some clarification is in order here. The first thing to
understand is that “hedge fund” has come to be used the way the Left (and
science-fiction writers) use the word “corporation,” meaning: men and
institutions with a great deal of money doing things that I do not understand,
who must, therefore, be evil. Indeed, the current discussion about the taxation
of financial firms is a terrific example of how the good-guys/bad-guys school
of policy analysis makes people stupid. Whether you believe that financial
firms are the nexus of evil in the 21st century or are the last outpost of
heroic Randian capitalism, it is worth your time to understand what they are
and what they do, inasmuch as solutions to problems you don’t understand aren’t
generally good ones.
The carried-interest question is in fact something that
is rarely very relevant to hedge funds. It is of much more interest to private-equity
firms, which are a different animal. Hedge funds are partnerships that
generally pursue high-risk, high-yield (and generally high-leverage) investment
strategies on behalf of people and institutions with lots of money; they are
called “hedge” funds because their original purpose was to provide big
investors with a hedge against unexpected developments in their less exotic
portfolios. Prominent hedge funds include Bridgewater Associates, BlackRock
Advisors, and Paulson & Co., and they are involved in everything from
high-frequency trading to event arbitrage. They rarely have the opportunity to
avail themselves of the 15 percent long-term capital-gains tax rate, because
that applies only to assets held for a year or more, and most hedge funds
operate on a much shorter timetable than that. (There are exceptions; John
Paulson is a collector of Steinway pianos, and Paulson & Co. purchased the
struggling Steinway & Sons outright a few years ago.) Their management fees
are generally taxed as ordinary income, as are most of their profits. In the
event that a hedge fund holds an investment for a year or more, any associated
capital gains would be taxed at the 15 percent long-term rate — the same as
they would for any other company, or for you as an individual.
Which isn’t to say that hedge funds happily turn 40
percent of their profits over to federal/state/local governments; they pursue
all sorts of tax-avoidance strategies, but the carried-interest strategy isn’t
usually one of them; there’s a very good discussion in the New York Times under
the headline “Why Hedge Funds Don’t Worry about Carried-Interest Tax Rules.” If
you want to raise taxes on hedge funds, changing carried-interest rules isn’t
how you do it — it would be a lot more complicated than that.
Carried interest — a share of the profits from a company
or an investment paid to the investment manager as a form of payment beyond
funds invested — is of much more acute concern to private-equity investors. (A
complication: Some hedge funds make private-equity investments.) The
distinction between the two kinds of companies is not mere financial esoterica,
especially if you are campaigning to be put in charge of tax reform. There are
many different kinds of private-equity investors: There are private-equity
firms that invest in troubled companies with the goal of restructuring them and
creating something profitable, which is what Mitt Romney did (with great success)
at Bain Capital. Your Sand Hill Road venture capitalists funding Silicon Valley
technology startups are another species of private-equity investor, as are the
so-called angel investors (high-net-worth individuals who put money directly
into private companies, also generally startups). And that is where the
carried-interest rule really comes into play.
While the analogy is not 100 percent accurate, if you’ve
ever been given stock options as part of your compensation, you’ll recognize
the general outline. Somewhere in a shoebox, I have a stock-option document
entitling me to buy a certain number of shares in a now-defunct
newspaper-publishing company; the options were part of my compensation as a
newspaper editor. If memory serves, I was given the option to buy stock at $27
a share at a time when the shares were trading at $18. That’s not unusual — the
idea is to get managers personally invested in the well-being of the company
(as reflected in its share price) in order to create good management incentives.
Because the options have no value at the time they are issued (you’re no richer
for having the opportunity to pay $27 for an $18 stock), there is no tax
liability at that point. But if you hold onto them and the company becomes more
valuable, then you stand to make some money. If the share price should go up to
$50 (alas, this did not happen with my newspaper company), then those $27
options are valuable — you can make $23 a share. Assuming that you’ve held
those options for more than a year, you’d be taxed at the 15 percent long-term
capital-gains rate rather than at the individual-income-tax rate.
Private-equity firms don’t just bring money to the table:
They bring (at least theoretically) expertise and labor, in exchange for which
they are given a percentage of ownership or profits beyond that associated with
the money they put up. If they hold those investments for a year or more and
there are profits realized, then they are taxed the same way you would be,
i.e., at the 15 percent rate. This is true even when they haven’t put up
investment capital for that portion of the deal, but have instead put up what
is sometimes called “sweat equity,” i.e., their work. If the deal goes south,
then the private-equity investors will not necessarily have lost money on the
management-fee portion of the deal, but they will have lost opportunity, time,
effort, etc. And in most cases they will have lost money, too, especially in
the case of venture capitalists, who much of the time will have put up
practically all the investment capital in a startup.
The case against the carried-interest rule is, in short,
that private-equity firms shouldn’t be allowed to treat investment income as a
long-term capital gain in situations where they didn’t have money at risk.
(This argument is, to be sure, not without some merit.) But private-equity
firms are not the only investors who profit on sweat equity. Consider the case
of the Silicon Valley worker bee: A programmer who might command $200,000 a
year at a Microsoft or a Google decides to go to work for a startup that cannot
afford to give him a salary like that; instead, he accepts equity in the firm,
in the hopes that it will be successful and he’ll get a big payday down the
road. Say the company in its early stages is valued at $20 a share and he is
given options at $22 a share — there is no “taxable event” in being given those
worthless (at the time) options, and if he ends up making $10 million on them
five years down the road, he pays the 15 percent rate, not the top
individual-income-tax rate, even though what he put up was his time and work,
not investment capital. The case for taxing the carried interest of
private-equity firms at ordinary income rates is also the case for taxing those
Silicon Valley foot soldiers at the ordinary rate. What that would mean is that
the tax incentives we give in exchange for risk-taking would be applicable only
to capital, while labor was shut out.
Which brings us to the question of why some forms of
income are taxed at different rates than others. We have a long, bipartisan
tradition of taxing long-term capital gains and dividends at lower rates for a
couple of reasons. In the case of dividends, the question is mostly double
taxation: Dividends are paid out of post-tax corporate income, which means out
of a pool of money that already has been taxed at the corporate tax rate — and
the United States has the developed world’s highest corporate tax rate (39
percent). For private investors, investments are generally made out of income
that already has been taxed: You pay 39 percent on your salary and, if you have
the prudence to save some of that salary and invest it, you get taxed again on
any money you make, and it strikes many people as sensible that the second bite
be smaller than the first. Where double taxation is not a concern, the idea is
that we need entrepreneurs and startups, and the firms that invest in them, to
make the economy go: If we’re all salaried middle-managers at Bob’s Insurance Inc.,
then there’s not much innovation, and little if any of the dramatic growth and
dynamism provided by innovative new firms. It may be that you think this is a
bad policy — and I think there is a pretty good case for taxing all income
regardless of its source at the same rate, once — but that’s an argument
against lower tax rates for investment categorically, not an argument against
lower tax rates for investors you don’t like. It’s also an argument against
having corporate income taxes and other sources of double taxation.
My own view is that private-equity firms do a great deal
of good for our economy, especially the venture-capital firms that fund
startups. Hedge funds and other more exotic financial specimens do valuable
work, too, although the benefits they provide (mainly risk mitigation) are less
obvious to the general population. But it is the case that where certain kinds
of income receive preferential tax treatment, firms and individuals will seek
to organize their incomes in such a way as to benefit from those rules.
Similarly, unless Washington should take the (unthinkably destructive) step of
banning U.S. firms from having overseas subsidiaries and partnerships, the
offshoring of profits for the purposes of shielding them from high U.S.
corporate tax rates is inevitable.
It is useful to meditate on that sky-high U.S. corporate
tax rate. On paper, it is, as noted above, the world’s highest; in reality,
most U.S. firms, especially large and politically connected firms, pay a lot
less than the official rate. That’s partly because the U.S. tax code is larded
with political favoritism, and partly because companies engage in other forms
of tax minimization. One of the difficulties of financial regulation is that
Goldman Sachs is regulated mainly by people who weren’t smart enough to get
jobs at Goldman Sachs; by the same token, the people who write the tax code
aren’t as smart or as motivated as the people who have billions of dollars at
stake reacting to it. You can jack up the tax rate on investments to whatever
you like — that doesn’t mean that anybody is going to pay it.
But don’t call it a “loophole.” This isn’t an unintended
feature of the tax code. The tax code was written the way it was for a reason.
Maybe you don’t think that it’s a good reason, but it isn’t an accident. And
there are no special rules for hedge funds or private-equity companies — they
play by the same rules the rest of us do, even if they’re better at it.
Not that this matters all that much in the big fiscal
picture. As Mr. Fleischer of the Times points out, the top 25 hedge-fund
managers earned between them about $21 billion in 2013. Those are very big
paychecks, but there aren’t a lot of them. If Washington were to take 70
percent of that haul, that would be only $14.7 billion, which in total would
fund federal operations from about 8 a.m. to 9:45 p.m. on any given Tuesday. A
few Democratic grandees might experience an enjoyable frisson from sticking it
to “the hedge-fund guys,” to be sure. So, “Let them eat fairness.”
One possible solution to all this would be to reform the
tax code in such a way that it was less costly to pay the tax man than to pay a
team of lawyers, accountants, and financial engineers to run interference
against the tax man. Crazy talk, right? Regardless, soaking Wall Street will
not solve the fundamental political problem underlying our unbalanced national
finances: The American middle class wants a much larger welfare state than it
is willing to pay for.
No comments:
Post a Comment