By Brink Lindsey & Steven Teles
Tuesday, November 07, 2017
Conservatives have two intellectual commitments that are
increasingly incompatible. They believe that the American economy is clogged up
with crony-capitalist corruption that hands out special favors and protections
to organized interests. They also hold that economic inequality — in
particular, the surging share of total income earned by those at the very top —
is morally justified by the rights of property and the tendency of free markets
to raise living standards overall.
These two commitments can no longer be squared. If our
economy really is riddled with cronyism, then the beneficiaries must have
pocketed large amounts of ill-gotten loot. The existing distribution of income
and wealth, therefore, does not deserve the deference it would be due if all gains
were derived from spontaneous, unregulated market transactions. Call it the
conservative inequality paradox: Either conservatives have overstated the
amount of crony capitalism, or their dismissal of the concept of inequality as
envy is misplaced.
In our new book The
Captured Economy, we argue that conservatives are not mistaken about the
extent of what we call “regressive regulation” — government-created distortions
of markets that have the effect of funneling income and wealth up the
socioeconomic scale. Such schemes of upward redistribution have proliferated in
the past few decades, an era that is often misunderstood as one of unceasing
deregulation. And because these reverse–Robin Hood policies work by squelching
and misdirecting competition, they exert a powerful downward drag on output and
growth as well.
Accordingly, conservatives should redouble their
willingness to attack these forms of regulation that — unlike health, safety,
and environmental rules, which impose (sometimes necessary, sometimes
excessive) costs on business — actually boost corporate profits by creating
market distortions, including barriers to entry for new competitors. In
addition, conservatives need to examine their instinctive defense of business
interests and their hostility to redistribution. But that doesn’t mean
conservatives need to become Bernie bros. There is a distinctly conservative
way of addressing inequality in a world of crony capitalism — one that seeks to
attack the inequality resulting from anti-market, growth-killing policies.
***
Progressives may rant about “neoliberal” markets run
amok, but many conservatives understand clearly that the U.S. economy is far
from a textbook model of free competition and voluntary exchange. Senator Mike
Lee, for example, has argued that “cronyist policies come in many shapes and
sizes — from subsidies and loan guarantees to tax loopholes and protective
regulation — but they all work the same way: The elite leaders of big
government, big business, and big special interests collude to help each other
climb to the highest rungs of success, and then pull up the ladder behind
them.” And in the 2015 debate over the Export-Import Bank, which primarily
subsidizes big-business exports, soon-to-be House speaker Paul Ryan rejected
claims that the existence of similar subsidies abroad justified providing them
here. “We should be leading by example,” he said. “We should be exporting
democratic capitalism, not crony capitalism.”
If anything, conservatives have been too modest in their
assessment of the breadth and scope of crony capitalism. In our book, we focus
on four big case studies: financial regulation, patent and copyright law,
occupational licensing, and zoning. In all of them, government-caused market
distortions have been growing rapidly over recent decades. Between 1980 and
2006, the financial sector as a percentage of GDP grew by almost 70 percent,
fed by regulatory subsidies for securitized mortgages and a string of “too big
to fail” bailouts. Copyright terms have lengthened from a maximum of 56 years
to the current life of the author plus 70 years, while laxer standards for
patentability have caused a nearly 400 percent increase in the number of
patents awarded annually. This excessive expansion has created a field day for
lawyers and inflated profits for Hollywood, big pharma, and Silicon Valley with
higher prices and licensing fees. But new innovators faced with traversing this
legal minefield are not so fortunate.
In 1970, only one in ten Americans worked in a job
subject to mandatory government licensing; now it’s closer to one in three.
Most of that growth has occurred because of a huge expansion in the number of
licensed occupations, now over 1,100 and counting. And in the nation’s big
coastal cities, increasingly restrictive zoning has levied an ever more
burdensome tax on new-housing construction — equal to 50 percent of the total
price of housing in Manhattan, San Francisco, and San Jose. While boosting
real-estate values for lucky legacy homeowners, zoning has imposed a serious
drag on national economic output — as much as 10 percent, according to recent
estimates. The loss is due to geographic misallocation of the labor force: The
country’s most productive places can’t accommodate all the people who want to
live and work there.
But do these market distortions really have anything to
do with inequality? After all, the pursuit of profit through the political
system (what economists call “rent-seeking”) is nothing new: James Madison was
writing about the problem of “faction,” or special-interest corruption, in The Federalist Papers 230 years ago.
Conservatives as a rule have failed to see a connection
between government policies and changes in the income distribution. Harvard
economist Greg Mankiw, who served as President George W. Bush’s top economic
adviser, displayed this blind spot in a 2013 article in the Journal of Economic Perspectives
entitled “Defending the One Percent.” “There is no good reason to believe,” he
wrote, “that rent-seeking by the rich is more pervasive today than it was in
the 1970s, when the income share of the top 1 percent was much lower than it is
today.”
The problems with this analysis are apparent once you
scrutinize who exactly occupies the apex of America’s economic pyramid.
Financial professionals and managers made up 14 percent of the top 1 percent in
2005, up from 8 percent in 1979. And while top financial executives earned the
same as their peers in other industries in 1980, they were making a 250 percent
premium by 2006. Doctors accounted for 16 percent of the top 1 percent in 2005,
while lawyers accounted for 8 percent. The representation of doctors and
lawyers in the top-earners’ club has been quite stable for decades; this means
that their incomes have been growing much faster than the incomes of most other
Americans, since the threshold for entering the top 1 percent has been moving
up rapidly over time as incomes get more unequal. Doctors and lawyers both use
occupational licensing to raise their incomes by restricting the supply of
practitioners and use the state to inflate demand for their services — in the
case of doctors, primarily through their influence over Medicare-reimbursement
schedules; in the case of lawyers, by larding up every law and regulation with
dysfunctional but highly litigable complexity.
So nearly 40 percent of earners at the top of the income
distribution are finance professionals, doctors, or lawyers — all major
beneficiaries of government largesse at our expense. Corporate executives make
up another 31 percent of the top 1 percent, and a healthy chunk of them are in
industries (such as movies, recorded music, or pharmaceuticals) whose profit
margins are fattened by government policy.
Even if it were true, as Mankiw contends, that
rent-seeking by the rich is no more prevalent now than in the past, incomes at
the top are nonetheless swollen with government-created rents. Top-end
inequality — the percentage of total income that goes to earners in the top
centile — could therefore be reduced significantly if those benefits were
eliminated or reduced through policy reforms.
Meanwhile, a review of America’s changing political
economy makes clear that, while rent-seeking has been a constant, its
distributional consequences have clearly changed over time. Beginning with the
New Deal, the initial decades of activist government featured a great deal of
downward redistribution: The National Labor Relations Act encouraged unions;
the Davis-Bacon Act raised wages on government contracts; the minimum wage was
relatively high; the federal government set universal-service requirements for
telephones and utilities; municipalities inaugurated rent control and
tenant-protection laws. Such policies feature much less prominently today.
Of course, there was plenty of New Deal–era government
intervention in behalf of business as well, including high trade barriers and
price and entry controls for airlines and trucking. But because the affected
industries typically employed large numbers of semi-skilled, unionized workers,
a substantial portion of the rents to business ended up shared with workers
earning modest incomes. Today, by contrast, the technologically leading
industries that occupy the “commanding heights” of the economy (and that thus
tend to be the focus of industry-specific regulation) mostly employ highly
skilled workers. Government favoritism for those industries thus mostly
benefits the well-off. Accordingly, the evidence strongly supports our
contention that rent-seeking has moved upmarket — and, therefore, that a good
chunk of the rich’s income is indefensible.
***
Conservative attitudes on inequality have long been
shaped by Robert Nozick’s famous metaphor of the basketball player Wilt
Chamberlain. Nozick argued that Chamberlain’s high income was derived from
mutually beneficial exchange and was therefore justifiable. Who could say that
there was anything unfair about a basketball player trading his skills for the
money of fans? And how could a distribution of income produced by that sort of
mutual exchange be unfair?
But the Wilt Chamberlain metaphor does not apply to an
economy characterized by extensive high-end rent-seeking. Even if you believe
that market returns are inherently just and therefore worthy of being defended
on ethical grounds, how do you justify windfalls that are a function of
distorted rules of the game? The answer is you can’t.
In the best of all worlds, conservatives would respond to
this state of affairs by attacking rent-derived inequality at its source. Their
economic agenda would focus on curtailing subsidies for finance, excessive
protection of intellectual property, the licensing of high-end professionals,
and overly restrictive land-use regulation. Doing so wouldn’t require
conservatives to become crusading egalitarians, as these reforms would also
unleash economic dynamism, innovation, and growth — familiar conservative
priorities.
Nevertheless, making regressive regulation a conservative
priority would be a distinct change in approach. Too often, conservatives’ idea
of a pro-growth policy agenda starts and ends with tax cuts, despite the
overwhelming evidence that moderate increases or decreases in the top rate have
little effect on growth. When conservatives do turn their attention to
regulation, they usually think about providing “regulatory relief” for business
by lightening health, safety, environmental, and labor regulations. In our
view, though, the regulations with the most pernicious economic effects are the
ones that subsidize business by blocking competition or by otherwise distorting
markets.
In some cases, conservatives would be able to build on
existing strengths when conducting such a campaign. Much of the mischief caused
by regressive regulation occurs at the state and local levels: occupational-licensing
rules, land-use regulations, and a host of other industry-specific
protectionist policies such as those that limit competition for auto dealers,
undertakers, and hospitals. A network of free-market think tanks and activist
groups is already up and running to push back against this rent-seeking — but
these organizations could be doing a lot more. There is no way to fight
regulatory capture by the well-off unless other wealthy people make
countervailing efforts to even the political playing field, creating the
institutional infrastructure needed to ensure that rent-seekers face determined
opposition. Conservatives can provide that countervailing power by deepening
their investments in state and local policy reform.
In one important respect, conservatives would need to
execute a complete change of direction. For decades now, conservatives have
favored slashing congressional staff and eliminating congressional support
agencies such as the Office of Technology Assessment. These are false economies,
as all they do is make Congress’s shrunken army of under-resourced patronage
staff ever more deeply dependent on industry lobbyists for the information
legislators need to govern. To insulate our politics more effectively against
insider takeover, legislators need to be able to draw on deep internal
expertise. As Lee Drutman and one of us (Teles) argued in a 2015 Washington Monthly piece, “A New Agenda
for Political Reform,” a major upgrade of legislative staff with a larger,
better-paid, and more professional cadre of civil servants would arm Congress
with the knowledge needed to counter the rent-seeking lobbies that seek to
twist rules to their own advantage.
Even if conservatives were to take our advice, a
sustained campaign against regressive regulation would not meet with quick,
easy victories. What awaits is, in the words of Max Weber, “the slow boring of
hard boards.” The disproportionate influence of the wealthy over the basic
rules of the economy is deeply embedded, and the best we can do is chip away at
it, a little at a time.
***
That leaves a hard question, namely, how conservatives
should think about inequality in a fallen, second-best world in which so many
of these rents survive. At a minimum, there’s a strong case for reconsidering
the conservative obsession with reducing top marginal income-tax rates. For too
long, conservatives have overhyped the growth effects of tax cuts, as well as
the dubious “starve the beast” theory according to which members of Congress
would respond to tax cuts by restraining government spending. Many
conservatives did not look carefully at the evidence behind these dodgy
empirical claims because they believed that they held the moral trump card: By
cutting taxes, they were returning wealth to its rightful owners. But in the
“captured economy” we’re currently living in, this belief is due for
reexamination. Not only is a significant fraction of the rich’s income morally
tainted by government favoritism, but it is also used to fund yet more rounds
of regressive rent-seeking.
One way to begin solving this problem would be to build a
veritable bonfire of the deductions that the wealthy use to shield their income
from taxation. The exclusion from taxes of employer-paid health insurance,
retirement savings through 401(k)s and IRAs, and education savings accounts
could either be scrapped or converted into refundable tax credits. We could
also consider a financial-transaction tax, which could raise a lot of revenue
while also reducing the incentives for excessive trading of assets. Changes
such as these would allow us to claw back some of the rents at the top of the
economy without increasing the marginal income-tax rates that conservatives are
so concerned with.
If conservatives took seriously the presence of
ill-gotten gains at the top of the income spectrum, they might also look at
immigration policy in a new light. Over the past few decades, the United States
has exposed those at the bottom of the economic pile to intense global
competition, whether in the form of products from China or workers from Mexico.
As Dean Baker has argued, it is high time to expose the wealthy to those same
bracing forces of competition by opening up the economy to more high-skilled
immigrants, especially in protected professions such as medicine and dentistry.
Conservatives need to face and resolve their inequality
paradox. They must double down on their principled advocacy of free,
competitive markets — while taking a few giant steps back from the assumption
that large incomes reflect large contributions to the general welfare.
No comments:
Post a Comment