By Jonathan Nicastro
Thursday, June 22, 2023
Some on the right want conservatives to pursue more
activist industrial policy. The think tank American Compass, founded by former
Mitt Romney economic adviser Oren Cass, has been among the leading
organizations calling for this change. In its recent publication, “Rebuilding American Capitalism: A Handbook for Conservative
Policymakers,” the section on industry demonstrates poor economic reasoning
and would be a recipe for failure.
The blurb for this section begins by describing
agriculture, manufacturing, and resource extraction as the industries that
“deliver the most productivity growth” and “foster technological progress.” In
one of the section’s memos, Tablet columnist Michael Lind
argues that “all industries are not created equal.” Specifically, Lind claims
that the nontraded-local-service sector enriches the country less than consumer
electronics, automobiles, and aerospace manufacturing.
But to lament the shift from manufacturing towards a
service-driven economy is to endorse economic regression — to return to a
reality in which people need to work more for less.
Manufacturing has become a lower share of overall employment in the U.S. not
because the U.S. makes less stuff, but because it takes fewer people to make
stuff now than it did 50 years ago. That increase in what economists call
“total factor productivity” is a sign of economic development, and it has
occurred in every country that advances to higher levels of per capita income.
The first subsection, “Create Demand for Domestic
Manufacturing,” is riddled with more fallacies. It proposes to “establish a 50%
local content requirement (LCR) for goods that are critical to national
security or the industrial base.” If LCRs are precisely prescribed, a 50
percent requirement seems rather round to have been calculated with any degree
of technical rigor. Moreover, if LCRs are such a boon, why stop at 50 percent
for only some goods? The report claims that LCRs create guaranteed demand for
domestic production. This is correct, insofar as LCRs mandate domestic inputs
for final goods (i.e., items ready for consumer purchase). But doing so would
increase production costs for domestic firms, translating to higher prices and
less demand for American-made consumer goods.
The report laments “artificially cheap” imports. But the
effect of Chinese steel subsidies, for example, is to reduce prices for
American-made steel-containing goods. By prohibiting American firms from
accessing such cheap inputs, the authors articulate a plan to diminish the
competitiveness of domestic firms, as occurred when President Trump imposed
tariffs on steel. Similarly to the LCRs, this would increase the demand for
imports, whose relative prices would decline, but the handbook elsewhere
prescribes a general tariff to make those more expensive as well. So American
consumers and businesses would be left paying higher prices for finished goods
and inputs to production whether they purchased them from home or abroad.
Other policies are similarly misguided. A proposal that
the Departments of Commerce and Defense determine which goods are “critical for
national security or the U.S. industrial base” would entrust government
officials with the power to direct economic production. Such credulity belies
conservatives’ skepticism of technocracy and top-down planning, and their
well-founded concerns about regulatory capture. As Dominic Pino observed of a similar act proposed by Josh Hawley, it
amounts to “a new way for incumbent firms to sic the federal government on
their competitors.”
Further misconceptions abound beyond the level of policy.
The report claims that offshoring “industrial capacity in pursuit of lower
costs diminished America’s ability to compete or innovate” over the past
several decades. But America is the most dynamically efficient economy in the
world — i.e., the most innovative. Although the level of innovation is hard to
quantify, one proxy is the value of a nation’s patents. The U.S. Department of
State, using data from PatentVector, reports that U.S. patents are
worth $3 trillion, while China’s are only worth $488 billion. Relatedly,
American R&D spending is the highest in the world: $668.4 billion or 28
percent of global R&D spending, as documented by the National Science Board.
Even though U.S. companies already lead the world in
R&D, the report calls for a government-led (read: taxpayer-funded)
research-and-development effort that would “match whatever funding industry
invests in a consortium with federal funds.” The goal of this policy is to
reclaim American supremacy in the fields of “semiconductors, aerospace, and
telecommunications.”
Just because something is assembled somewhere, however,
does not mean that it is produced there. The value-added chain is quite long,
and many of its most important stages are immaterial. Taiwan and China do have
significant market shares of some aspects of the global semiconductor value
chain, but according to an October 2020 report, America dominates overall — no CHIPS act required. The U.S.
controls over 60 percent of the “fabless” market, which designs but does not
manufacture nor assemble chips, while China’s share is less than 20 percent.
The American share of the integrated-device-manufacturers (IDM) market, which
designs, manufactures, and assembles chips, is approximately 50 percent,
compared with China’s near-zero. Intel chips are not assembled in
the U.S., but they are ideated, innovated, and iterated upon here.
Again displaying envy of other nations, the report argues
that an “American development bank,” modeled after the European Investment
Bank, could helpfully reduce the risk incurred by “longer-term, higher-risk,
lower-return projects.” This is really an argument for moral hazard. When a
person, firm, or government does not bear the costs of poor investment
decisions, that entity is liable to make more such decisions. Who bears the
cost? The American taxpayer. To prefer new national-level programs on top of
existing private and public funding mechanisms is to ignore that mammoth public
investment inevitably results in overcapacity, waste, graft, and a lack of
innovation (see: the F-35 fighter-jet program).
One industry allegedly in need of help from such a bank
is “the commercial maritime industry,” which it would help “modernize.” But
that industry is already the beneficiary (or victim) of more protectionism and
government support than nearly any other. The Jones Act was passed to ensure
“adequate domestic shipbuilding capacity” in the event of war by restricting
“water transportation of cargo between U.S. ports to ships that are U.S.-owned,
U.S.-crewed, U.S.-registered, and U.S.-built,” as the Cato Institute describes
in a report. The Jones Act achieved the opposite of its stated
purpose, but American Compass thinks it will get the protectionist formula
right this time.
The final subsection, “Let America Build Again,” calls
for the repeal of the National Environmental Policy Act of 1970. Give credit
where it’s due: It rightly blames the NEPA for “imposing red tape on energy and
infrastructure projects and triggering environmental reviews.” Environmental
reviews have also empowered NIMBYs to prohibit the construction of new
dwellings, which has harmed our lowest-income earners, who cannot afford to
adequately house themselves and their families. But this is an exception to the
section’s overall character.
Those at American Compass cannot casually disregard
substantive economic arguments against its top-down planning as what Lind
caricatures as “family-wrecking, nation-weakening libertarian globalism.” The
burden of proof is on them to justify their technocratic machinations — a
position conservatives ordinarily oppose.
No comments:
Post a Comment