By Jonah Goldberg
Wednesday, October 23, 2024
Every career involves learning some lessons the hard way.
I actually think you could do a fun symposium or essay series called “Lessons
Learned the Hard Way.” I’m sure every experienced person has a story to back up
their advice, from the lion tamer (“make sure you start when they’re young”) to
the Hezbollah communications equipment procurement guy (“check your supply
chain closely”).
I bring this up for a bunch of reasons (this “news”letter
promises to be a bit of a ride). One lesson I learned the hard way: There are a
lot of different kinds of libertarians.
I don’t want to go too far down memory lane, or too deep
down rabbit holes, but the gist is that a long time ago I got into fights with
some small but often very loud and cranky libertarian sects, and I made the
mistake of accepting that they spoke for libertarians generally. This was very
unfair to a lot of libertarians who have very different views. For years after,
a lot of normal, sane, decent, libertarians were still pissed at me for things
I said about “libertarians” that really only applied to, say, the Ron Paul or
Lew Rockwell crowd.
It was a good reminder that many who claim to speak
authoritatively for an idea or group are, in fact, simply trying to steal the
intellectual or moral authority of a label. Not everyone who insists they are
speaking for a group is telling you the truth, even if they think they are. Not
all self-described feminist leaders speak authoritatively for women. There are
lots of people who claim to be spokespersons for Christianity, Judaism,
conservatism, progressivism, etc. who are in fact just pushing a narrow agenda.
But the relevant lesson I learned: There are many
different kinds of libertarians, a point I promise to return to.
I should note that all broad ideological and religious
groups have really weird internal sectarian battle lines that are largely
invisible to people outside the fishbowl. I don’t know much about the schism
between the Missouri Synod Lutherans and the Evangelical Lutheran Church, but I
know it’s a thing. I can tell you a lot about the fault lines within
intellectual conservatism. Some tribes get along just fine with each other.
Some do not. But what we all know, to one extent or another, are the shibboleths
and ideological lodestars that separate us. But these dividing lines are often
invisible to outsiders.
The left used to have the best schisms. Most
non-communists couldn’t tell you the difference between Mikhail Bakunin and
Karl Marx, but boy oh boy, their acolytes hated each other. Bolsheviks and
Mensheviks, Trotskyites and Stalinists, Eurocommunists versus Soviet
Communists, the Lovestoneites versus the Ruthenbergians, it goes on and on.
That’s why the “People’s
Front of Judea versus the Judean Peoples’ Front” thing is so funny.
My favorite schism is probably the Hatfield-McCoy-esque
battle between The Amalgamated Order of Real Bearded Santas and the Red Suit
Society chronicled by This
American Life.
You’re probably asking yourself about now, “Did I leave
the stove on?” You also might be asking why I’m saying all this. Well, first,
because I love this stuff.
Also, I think the narcissism of small differences is
among the most important, and definitely one the most interesting, drivers of
political and cultural conflict. Also, I think the most interesting arguments
are between groups that generally agree on first principles but differ wildly
on where they go with their disagreements. These arguments are interesting
because they revolve around the hard cases, where principles are in conflict
and difficult choices are necessary. Arguments between capitalists and communists
can be entertaining, but they rarely get far past the starting line. Debates
between, say, foreign policy neoconservatives and conservative realists, Social
Democrats and socialists, Russian Orthodox Christians and Catholics, Sunni and
Shiites, AORB Santas and RSS Santas go way down the racetrack before they fight
for the checkered flag.
But the main reason I point all this out is that I need
to ease into the argument I’m going to make. So, let’s get back to
libertarians.
As I said, there are many, many, rooms in the mansion of
libertarianism. This intellectual diversity is uniquely interesting because
many libertarians deny this, claiming that libertarianism is a clear and
perfectly consistent philosophy. In 2001 I got into a spat
with Harry
Browne, the 2000 Libertarian Party presidential candidate, on this very
point. Browne argued that libertarians are “consistently on one side on every
issue,” which is a weird thing to say for someone who spent so much time with
libertarians.
There are left-libertarians and right-libertarians. There
are libertarians who call themselves conservatives and there are conservatives
who call themselves libertarians. The gang at Reason is not the same
kind of libertarian crowd as the one at the Mises Institute. Even among the
subgroups there are divisions. I guarantee that the good folks at Cato have
arguments in the lunchroom from time to time. Many people think Randians are
libertarians, but Ayn Rand emphatically didn’t—and even if many Randians
identify as libertarian, their leaders often take after their founding mother
and score poorly on “Plays well with others.” And Friedrich Hayek, often
considered the patron saint of libertarianism, did not call himself one (he was
a lovable “Old Whig”). Meanwhile, the Libertarian Party of New Hampshire is a dumpster
fire that, from what I can tell, no decent libertarian wants to be
associated with. Its Twitter account recently posted,
“Anyone who murders Kamala Harris would be an American hero.” Hell, there’s
been a decades-long simmering libertarian civil war over … the
Civil War.
So let’s put aside the ideological definitions for a
moment and talk about personality types.
I am a longtime
critic of using
psychology to explain ideological positions. Jonathan Haidt has moved me off
some of my more strident views in this regard, but I still think a lot of
psychological explanations for political disagreements are invidious borderline
phrenology-level garbage.
Yet, I think it’s true that some people do come to their
ideological commitments via their personality or psychology. Some radicals
really are simply the kind of people who want to see the world burn. Some
conservatives are just natural curmudgeons. Some progressives (and
conservatives!) just think the world should be “good” and they don’t really
care about the arguments or the trade-offs that come with pursuing their goals.
But there is a kind of libertarian whom we used to call
“left-brained” (though the whole left-brain right-brain thing is basically a
myth). Today we might say some of them are “high-functioning” but “on the
spectrum” (I don’t mean this as pejorative—some of the most brilliant and
decent people I’ve ever met fit this description). We all know the type, and if
you don’t it’s very possible that you are the type. They’re extremely
logical and categorical in their thinking. They are impatient with the
messiness of emotions and interpersonal dynamics. They are often blunt in a way
that is indistinguishable from arrogance. I think it’s fair to
say that these people, mostly men, are overrepresented in fields like
engineering. By no means are they all socially awkward or “spectrum-y,” but
they all love to follow “the data” and “maximize efficiency.”
I have no idea if there’s any data on how they are
distributed ideologically, but in my experience a lot of them are really into
economics, particularly free market economics, for the same reason some people
are naturally in love with mathematics. Complete and rational metaphysical
systems external to ourselves have a kind of religious pull for some people. In
their youth they often have a heavy Ayn Rand phase because Randianism extols
individual achievement and efficiency without regard to the feelings of the
masses.
Let me tell you a quick true story. Twenty years ago, I
used to debate libertarians a lot. One of my most popular debate partners (I’ll
leave his name out of it), was a great guy (and I’m he sure still is). We’d
have fun debating privatizing lighthouses and all the rest. It became an annual
affair with beers and laughs from the audience. Then the last time we did it,
the debate fell flat. My opponent had switched careers from journalism to
finance. And in the process, his outlook changed. He went from touting the
brilliance of the invisible hand to believing that the hand of the state needed
simply to impose efficiencies the political process was too dumb, lazy, or
corrupt to impose. He wanted a libertarian monarch or national CEO of sorts to
cut through the red tape and the political dysfunction.
Indeed, a more mainstream version of this thinking can be
found in the unkillable idea that the government should be “run like a
business.” I don’t have time to explain (again)
why, but the simple fact is you can’t run government like a business because it
isn’t one. (And it really shouldn’t be!) Anyway, the point of the story is that
my libertarian sparring partner was, in many of the ways that matter most, no
longer a libertarian. He was better described as a technocrat who understood
that libertarians are right in theory but not up to the job in practice.
This sub-group of libertarians tends to reduce man to homo
economicus, a purely rational economic actor. Now, the history of the term homo
economicus is more complicated than you might think. John Stuart Mill, who
coined the phrase, did not believe that man was simply “economic man.” He said
that the field of political economy treated men as purely rational
maximizers of economic advantage. But he emphatically did not believe that
political economy was the sole or even best lens to look through. Adam Smith
and Friedrich Hayek definitely did not subscribe to the idea that man is just homo
economicus. But critics of Smith, Hayek, and their ideological followers
liked to pretend otherwise. The truth is that Marxism, not capitalism, comes
much closer to the cult of homo economicus.
Indeed, it would not surprise me in the slightest if, in
the 19th century, the personality types I’m talking about were
attracted to socialism or Marxism for similar reasons they are attracted to
libertarianism today. After all, there was a time when “scientific socialism”
had the frisson of gnostic heresy and metaphysical truth these guys find so
seductive. I know enough about the Progressive Era and the New Deal to be
highly confident many of those championing technocratic rule by “disinterested
experts” found the concept of “disinterestedness” conveniently congenial with
their personality types: “People like me should be in charge.”
For instance, Stuart Chase, the intellectual often
credited with coining the phrase “the New Deal,” once said, “I speak in
dispraise of dusty learning, and in disparagement of the historical technique.”
Chase wanted an “economic dictatorship” run by people like him. “Are our plans
wrong? Who knows? Can we tell from reading history? Hardly.” In his book, The
New Deal, he asked, “Why should Russians have all the fun of remaking [the]
world?”
Today, there are a bunch of so-called libertarians who
are equally ebullient about remaking the world. They see things like Artificial
Intelligence as a kind of Philosopher’s Stone
capable of transmogrifying the world. And they might be right!
The problem is that they are not what you might call
“natural libertarians” so much as “natural John Galts.” Their attraction to
free markets and economic efficiency comes from a different place than a love
for liberty qua liberty. For most, you’d never know it because they’ve become
acculturated into libertarianism and they work in institutions where there’s no
material temptation or incentive to move off of their ideological, cultural,
and political commitments. Even if they might be tempted, a free market
economist at a university or think tank doesn’t get a lot of offers to be part
of an authoritarian intellectual junta. They don’t get invitations or see
opportunities to become oligarchs.
But some see exactly that opportunity. Right now.
I don’t entirely trust all
of the reporting
on the tech billionaires flocking to Trump. I’m not questioning any
journalist’s integrity, I just know enough about some of the players—and enough
about how ideological outsiders miss important nuances and context when
reporting from outside the fishbowl—that I am open to the idea things are more
complex than the reporting suggests. (I have never read a story about any
institution I’ve been part of that adequately captured the internal dynamics of
that institution.)
Still, it seems obvious that a bunch of very rich people,
who once described themselves as libertarians, have concluded that
libertarianism won’t get the job done. Peter Thiel, a youthful fan of Ayn Rand,
was once a libertarian hero. He championed the idea of man-made
floating city-states in the middle of the ocean that would be a kind of
maritime Galt’s Gulch. The idea
was “to establish permanent, autonomous ocean communities to enable
experimentation and innovation with diverse social, political, and legal
systems.” During Covid, one such project in the Caribbean was launched and
Thiel proclaimed, “The nature of government is about to change at a very
fundamental level.”
Whatever you make of that stuff—I think it has some
appeal despite its Bond villain vibe—it appears that the super-investor has
hedged his bets. Rather than put all of his eggs on some Randian Casablanca in
international waters, he’s also investing in domestic American politics, and
perhaps changing American government at a very fundamental level. A
while back, Thiel struck up a friendship
with Curtis Yarvin,
the dashboard saint of the “neo-reactionary” or “Dark Enlightenment”
movement, which considers liberal democracy a failure. (If you’ve read Suicide
of the West, you know that I am completely and passionately on the opposite
side of that project.)
This is exactly one of those places where I think a
little skepticism and humility is in order. I have no idea if Thiel fully
subscribes to Yarvin’s lust for “techno-monarchy.” I know other intellectuals
in Thiel’s orbit who definitely don’t. Rich intellectuals—and Thiel is
certainly rich and an intellectual—often collect weird people they find amusing
or interesting. (I was once invited to have dinner with Thiel myself, though I
don’t think I made much of an impression). But we know that Thiel and his circle
have
made investments in Donald Trump. I have a friend who’s followed Thiel
closely for years. His theory is that Thiel doesn’t want to be an American
oligarch, but Thiel has reluctantly concluded that oligarchy is inevitable and
it’s better to be an oligarch in an oligarchy than not. Again, I don’t know if
that’s true. But I don’t know that it’s not, either.
And Thiel is hardly alone. Elon Musk, another spectrum-y,
hyper-intelligent, libertarianish John
Galt type, has clearly made a huge bet on Trump.
This is already very long. So I’ll stop offering examples
of other Silicon Valley techno-libertarians and crypto bros who have decided
that Trump is their best option. From everything I’ve heard and read, it seems
clear that none of these people think Trump is one of them. They think they can
use him, bribe him, herd him. It’s not an unreasonable bet. Trump has already
reversed himself completely on TikTok and crypto-currencies—even idiotically talking
about paying off the national debt with crypto currency.
What I want to close with is the intellectual fallacy at
the heart of this stuff. I keep hearing about people in this crowd talking
about how liberal democracy is an impediment to their cornucopian vision of
technological revolution, that AI is too important to leave to voters,
Congress, and the courts. I get it. If Thanos’ gauntlet or the genie’s lamp is
just over the horizon, why put up with committees and politicians who might get
in the way?
Contrary to the Dark Enlightenment bong-session fantasies
about moving beyond liberal democracy—which includes the rule of law, natural
rights, etc.—there is nothing beyond liberal democracy. It’s the summit. Its
precepts, as Calvin Coolidge and Francis Fukuyama argued, are final and cannot
be improved upon. It’s the edge of the map, and like those old medieval maps
said: Beyond, there be monsters. This isn’t some goody-goody, patriotic,
Enlightenment chauvinism. It’s certainly true that it’s better to be an
oligarch in an oligarchy. But oligarchy is bad. Moreover, oligarchy is not a
new idea. It’s a very old one. It’s one of the oldest ideas humans have. And
the problems with it—which are way too numerous to detail here—stem from the
very thing the “efficiency maximizers” and would-be John Galts don’t like about
politics in the first place. Human nature cannot be repealed; it can only be
channeled and harnessed to productive and moral ends.
To use language this crowd likes, liberal democracy is
antifragile and scalable. It provides avenues and mechanisms for
self-correction and adaptation. Yes, it can become sclerotic and dysfunctional,
but the solutions—literally the solvents—that clear the arteries is liberal
democracy itself. The hubris of the techno-monarchists or techno-oligarchs is
that with the right technology, which was made possible by liberal democracy in
the first place, you won’t need the system that made it possible. They point to
China as proof I’m wrong. But I look to China as proof I’m right. Whatever
problems we have, I’d rather have our problems than China’s.
The new technocrats, like the old technocrats, think the
solution to political problems is more data. But the kind of data they have in
mind is merely the epiphenomenon, the dye marker of homo economicus’ maneuvering.
The phenomenon of the human spirit is something more. Just as man does not live
by bread alone (even at affordable prices), experts cannot rule by data alone.
The kind of system they hint at, or perhaps lust for, is a machine that is
seductively beautiful on the drawing board. Engineers love machines and they
can make them do amazing things. But the machine of human society has a ghost
in it, the human spirit. And it is folly to think that engineers can master
that sustainably at scale, to use their terms.
Monarchy is a kind of monopoly on political power. It
“worked” when humanity was largely illiterate and unliberated. When enough of
humanity was liberated from ignorance, monarchy’s monopoly was unsustainable
because it was inadequate to the task of stifling innovation and human agency.
That’s not going to change with more data and better computing power.
Actual libertarians understand this. Lovers of systems of
pure logic who call themselves libertarians don’t.
No comments:
Post a Comment