National Review Online
Wednesday, January 24, 2018
Signaling that protectionist trade measures remain at the
top of his agenda, President Donald Trump imposed punitive duties on imported
solar panels and washing machines, a move intended to put pressure on
politically connected manufacturers in China, South Korea, and Mexico, and by
extension on the governments of those countries. This is a mistake.
Trump’s views on trade have always been and remain
foolish — he has been going on about the Asian economic Superman getting ready
to eat our lunch since Japan rather than China was the locus of our national
trade anxiety. This has led to many unfortunate outcomes, including the
abandonment of American leadership on trade-related issues: The U.S. decision
to abandon the Trans-Pacific Partnership, for example, has not derailed the project,
but simply left it to proceed with Canada rather than the United States taking
the lead while also giving China more leverage in its trade negotiations with
its neighbors. Trump called TPP “a terrible deal,” but he never explained his
objections in any meaningful detail, and his aides have been trying to
replicate some of its provisions in new trade deals.
Populists peddle tariffs as a punitive measure enacted on
shadowy foreign business interests, but what they are in fact is a sales tax on
American consumers. They protect inefficient producers by raising the prices of
competitors that consumers would otherwise prefer. Sometimes, that results in
the competitor being priced out of the market entirely, but it is just as often
the case that domestic producers simply take the opportunity to raise their
prices and broaden their profit margin. That’s fine for the CEOs and
shareholders of the favored firms, but it is a raw deal for Americans who end
up with higher prices and fewer choices.
Tariffs often end up having the opposite of the economic
effect desired, as economists have understood for a very long time. If, for
example, the United States puts a tariff on Japanese goods, that raises the
U.S. price of Japanese goods and hence reduces U.S. demand for Japanese
imports. (That is what protective tariffs are supposed to do.) That also
reduces U.S. demand for Japanese yen (since U.S. importers will be doing less
business with Japanese producers), reducing the value of the yen vis-à-vis the
U.S. dollar — and thereby making Japanese imports cheaper in the United States.
Which is to say, floating exchange rates essentially make an end run around
tariffs, rebalancing in the foreign-exchange markets what politicians distorted
with the tariff. What’s worse in this scenario is that the depressed Japanese
yen and reduced exports to the United States leave Japanese consumers with less
money with which to buy American goods, which are now more expensive to
Japanese buyers because of the falling yen. That’s why the most significant
development in the markets after Trump’s announcement wasn’t a crash in Chinese
washing-machine stocks — investors had been expecting the move for some time —
but a steep drop (1 percent in a few hours’ worth of trading) in the value of
the Mexican peso.
Protectionist measures always hurt consumers and often
end up enlarging rather than reducing trade deficits as consumers abroad buy
fewer U.S.-made goods. The president is obsessed with trade deficits, which are
not “deficits” in any real sense of the word (there isn’t any ballooning “trade
debt” comparable to the national debt) but instead are mere record-keeping
expressions that reflect certain economic realities. One of those realities is
that people in relatively poor countries — the so-called emerging markets —
have higher rates of savings, meaning that they use many of the dollars they
earn selling goods in the United States to purchase dollar-denominated
financial assets rather than consumer goods. The trade deficit is simply the
flipside of the capital surplus. The Koreans are not getting over on us by
providing Americans with excellent appliances at low prices. It is pure
superstition to think that they are.
Speaking of which: Samsung already manufactures
appliances in the United States, as do China’s Qingdao Haier and several other
Asian manufacturing giants. Many also operate in Canada and Mexico. Assuming
that they find themselves unable to simply pass costs along to consumers, it is
possible they could shift some production to the United States, but it is just
as likely if not more so that they would shift some production to Mexico, doing
most of the manufacturing work in their Asian factories but reserving final
assembly to a plant somewhere inside the NAFTA free-trade zone, where they will
have a considerably better chance of successfully contesting the tariffs.
Again, all tariffs would accomplish in this case would be to distort markets
and disrupt supply chains.
One might expect that the solar tariffs would put a
little extra jingle in the pockets of Elon Musk, Al Gore, and other investors
in solar power. But that isn’t likely to happen, either. About 80 percent of
the solar equipment installed in the United States is imported, and the $28
billion–a–year industry complains that it will be handicapped by these measures
rather than protected by them. The solar-industry trade association is
predicting the loss of 23,000 jobs this year. There are in fact only a few U.S.
firms engaged in the business of manufacturing solar panels. Kneecapping an
entire industry in the service of a handful of politically favored firms isn’t
shrewd economic policy — it’s crony capitalism.
The president shouldn’t be trying to interpose himself
between Americans and their washing machines.
No comments:
Post a Comment