By Jonah Goldberg
Wednesday, April 09, 2025
I just started writing this after the news broke that
President Donald Trump will “pause” most of the tariff insanity with most
non-Chinese countries for 90 days. Or some such.
Frankly, I didn’t get into the details because he had me
at “pause.” I’ve written and read a lot about Trump and his fakakta views
on trade. But there is one point about economics that I’d like to get out of my
head while it’s fresh and relevant.
Last week, I cited
a talk
by Robert McTeer, the former head of the Dallas Fed. This idea stuck with
me:
My solution is to stop keeping
foreign trade statistics. We don’t keep records on interstate trade between
Texas and California, so we don’t know which state has the deficit and which
has the surplus. And we don’t care. But if we kept the statistics, we would
know and the deficit state would do something foolish to correct the “problem.”
I liked this idea. So, on The Remnant, I asked our
very own Scott Lincicome whether the world would be better off if we didn’t
keep international trade statistics, basically putting him out of business.
Scott gave a very good answer that changed my mind. No, he said, because the
data we get from international trade is useful for making the case for free
trade. Without that data, politicians would be freer to do stupid stuff.
For instance, absent the evidence that it’s a bad idea, why
not protect American washing machine manufacturers from foreign
competition? I mean, those workers are Americans—and voters. It just seems
right. And, heck, if you don’t have the numbers showing that it’s ineffective,
inefficient, and counterproductive, then making the case against such
protectionism is harder.
Think of it this way: Ignaz Semmelweis was
the doctor who figured out that obstetricians should wash their hands before
delivering babies. The data showed that babies delivered by midwives had far
lower maternal mortality rates than wards where professionally trained doctors
delivered babies. The main reason was that the doctors would often go from
conducting autopsies to delivering babies without washing their hands. (I’ve
always thought it was gross that you wouldn’t wash your hands after mucking
around in the innards of dead people, regardless of what was next on your
itinerary. “Sure, I just yanked out some dead dude’s bowel with my bare hands.
No need to wash up though, I’m only going to have some peel-and-eat shrimp
now.”)
In 1847, he proposed that doctors at a Vienna hospital
sanitize their hands, and maternal deaths dropped dramatically. But the broader
medical profession rejected—even took offense at—his findings. It wasn’t until
years later, after Louis Pasteur confirmed the germ theory, that surgeons
started washing their hands as a matter of standard practice. Still, the point
is, the data led us toward a better practice even if the explanation for why
hand-washing was advisable didn’t come until later.
In retrospect, I think it’s really weird that McTeer
argued for a policy of blindness in a speech titled “Why Bastiat is my Hero.”
Frédéric Bastiat was the author of the canonical essay “That Which Is Seen, and That Which
Is Not Seen,” which lays out the parable of the broken window.
For those unfamiliar, the gist is that people tend to
only think about what is “seen,” without thinking about the unseen costs of an
action. In the parable, Bastiat tells a tale about a kid breaking a store
window. One of the onlookers says, “It is an ill wind that blows nobody good.
Everybody must live, and what would become of the glaziers if panes of glass
were never broken?”
“Now,” Bastiat responds, “this form of condolence
contains an entire theory, which it will be well to show up in this simple
case, seeing that it is precisely the same as that which, unhappily, regulates
the greater part of our economical institutions.”
From there he goes on to explain that the money it cost
to fix the window could have been spent on something more productive. “It is
not seen that as our shopkeeper has spent six francs upon one thing, he cannot
spend them upon another. It is not seen that if he had not had a window to
replace, he would, perhaps, have replaced his old shoes, or added another book
to his library. In short, he would have employed his six francs in some way,
which this accident has prevented.”
This is a wonderful introduction to the idea of
opportunity costs, unintended consequences, and, most importantly, human
intuitions about economics. Politicians constantly violate or ignore
opportunity costs and unintended consequences, but I’ll skip that stuff and go
straight to the point about intuitions.
Free market economics are not nearly so intuitive as
people who grow up in free market cultures often think. Not all intuitions are
innate, some are learned. Soldiers are trained to have different intuitions in
the face of enemy fire than normal people have. Bear trainers learn to have
different intuitions than the rest of us when confronting a grizzly. It is a
pretty natural human intuition to steal if you think you can get away with it.
But parents and society try to teach people not to give into it. I honestly
would have thought that washing your hands after doing gross stuff was a
natural human intuition given how instinctively it comes to me. But, apparently
not.
This is basically the whole point of my book Suicide
of the West. Teaching people to rise above instincts and baser desires is
what civilizing means. Civilized societies—i.e. civilizations large and
small—expect members to behave on more than raw instinctual desires.
To the extent our modern “economical intuitions” are
different from our innate ones, it’s because we grew up in a very
market-oriented culture.
Here’s a true story. When I briefly lived in Prague in
1991, we called our favorite restaurant “the pork knee place,” because they
served these giant haunches of roast pork. The knife and fork it came with were
like a short, serrated sword and small trident. Anyway, the pork knee place was
a popular joint during the communist days. Communist officials and other
well-connected types had long eaten there. Not surprisingly, it required
reservations. One time, we got there 10 or 15 minutes late. The restaurant refused
to honor the reservation. Okay, fair enough. But instead of giving the table to
someone else, they just picked the chairs up, put them upside down on the
table, and didn’t serve anyone. For the proprietors, our failure to show up on
time was an opportunity not to work. Forgoing what we would have paid—and
tipped!—for our meal was worth it. For us, it was utterly bewildering.
The Soviets never managed to create the New Soviet Man,
but they got closer than some folks realize.
Anyway, doing favors for friends and allies is natural.
Protecting the seen while ignoring the unseen is natural. It’s especially
natural for people involved in politics, modern or ancient. Politics is
naturally transactional. Absent facts, data, and the application of reason to
marshal arguments against special treatment for allies, favor-trading,
protectionism, and the rest, politicians will resort to precisely these
methods. We know this because that is often what politicians do despite the
evidence. Because political interests for a given politician are only rarely
perfectly aligned with the interests of the whole society. There are virtually no good arguments for,
say, rent control. But rent control endures in countless cities because the
beneficiaries are politically organized and concentrated and the victims
aren’t. We can see the beneficiaries, and politicians hear from
them.
Lincicome, a former well-compensated trade lawyer, made a
really useful point about how to think about free trade policy. The whole point
of free trade agreements is to get countries—i.e., the political leaders doing
the negotiating—to “tie their own hands” as much as possible. Every country has
some political sacred cows when it comes to trade. The French aren’t going to
abandon their protection of stinky cheese and pretentious wine. Americans have
an (irrational) opposition to foreigners owning farmland. The Swiss, despite
not being Hindus, have their own Calvinist version of actual
sacred cows. The trick is to constantly haggle over reducing the items on
everyone’s list of political untouchables. I don’t think that will ever really
change. But we can get closer.
But let’s say we could have a global free trade regime.
We have one in America. We have nearly complete free trade within the 50
states. I say “nearly” only because I think you could say that state or local
regulations serve as de facto “non-tariff” barriers to more efficient commerce.
California, for example, has all sorts of regulations that make gas and housing
more expensive. Those regulations are mostly bad for Californians, but
Californians get to make those decisions. Regardless, that’s an argument for
another time.
My point is that internal trade statistics don’t matter
very much because we have constitutionally locked-in free trade in this
country. Tennessee can’t put a tariff on Wisconsin cheese and Wisconsin can’t
tariff Maine’s cranberries. And we’re the richer for it. If we could do the
same on a global scale, there would undoubtedly be unseen, or unforeseen,
costs. But I think the benefits would outweigh them. And, as a result, tracking
international trade statistics wouldn’t be all that useful or necessary. In a
world of unbreakable windows, we wouldn’t need glaziers.
This is a kind of micro version of a larger point. Rules,
laws, customs, institutions, and things like science are necessary for
civilization because we are flawed. And, to borrow a phrase from Francis Bacon,
the “relief of man’s estate” is a perpetual project because humanity is always
a work in progress.
“If men were angels,” James Madison said, “no government
would be necessary.” It follows that if men were angels, we wouldn’t need all
of that stuff we use to make humanity better. Schools? Why bother? Courts? Who
needs them? Not only would we not need criminal laws, we also certainly
wouldn’t need to track crime statistics. Angels don’t murder, so why track the
homicide rate when it’s always zero? But men are not angels, so we have laws
against crime and we keep statistics about crime to help us figure out how to
have less of it. Trade statistics are really only necessary because they
illuminate deviations from the ideal. Just as in a world of unbreakable
windows, we wouldn’t need glaziers, in a world with angels for politicians, or
in a world of actual free trade, we wouldn’t need trade statistics—or modern
day Bastiats like Scott Lincicome.
No comments:
Post a Comment