By William Beach & Amity Shlaes
Thursday, July 11, 2024
Americans’ top concern this election year is the
economy, as CNN hosts pointed out when they opened the first presidential debate
of the election season.
President Biden more or less brushed off the question.
Almost any Democrat would do the same. The party prefers to pound the topic of
social injustice, relegating economic policy to a tool for social leveling.
Former president Trump did better, underscoring the value of his tax cuts. But
even the Donald didn’t deliver the kind of full-throated defense of capitalism
we heard in the years of Ronald Reagan or Barry Goldwater. The platform he released recently robustly assails inflation.
But it contains scant reference to the worst economic challenge that will drive
inflation, the federal debt. And when it comes to taxes, the specifics of the
plan are disappointingly narrow: tax cuts for workers and an end to taxation of
tips.
And that too is typical.
Republicans these days will fight for capitalism. But not
too hard.
Call it “conditional capitalism.” The “conditional” stems
from a spreading suspicion that the interests of markets conflict with the
interests of the average American. As Senator Marco Rubio put it recently, “what is best for the markets is not what
is best for the American people.” Most Republicans will still drop a few lines
about the merits of markets, or propose a mild reform — indexing capital gains,
say, or sustaining Trump’s tax cuts. But the days when campaigning Republicans
vied to propose the most dramatic tax cut — think of Dick Armey, Steve Forbes,
and Phil Gramm in 1996 in New Hampshire — are over. The old describer of tax
reforms, “across the board,” appears to be “obs.” — as in the sad little Oxford
English Dictionary abbreviation. In our times, Republicans are not above
hawking tariffs, as President Trump does. Or pushing for the breakup of big
companies. Especially when they think doing so draws votes away from Democrats.
You can explain the hesitation. We live, alas, in the Age
of Apology. We apologize for education. We apologize for purchases. We even
apologize for celebrating the Fourth of July. So, of course, we apologize for
free markets.
Still, unapologetic support for free enterprise has its
charms.
That at least is the evidence of the understudied records
of another moment of conditional capitalism, the period after World War I.
Armistice came in 1918, but it brought no economic peace
here at home. The burden of war debt dramatically restricted the ability of
lawmakers to spend. Yet angry returning veterans demanded benefits — the famous
“bonuses.” The vets’ families likewise cried out for federal support. Dropping
commodity prices shortly infuriated and bankrupted farms, driving farmers to
push for federal subsidy. Unacknowledged inflation made a mockery of pay stubs,
yet authorities preferred to blame merchants for high prices. Rioting crowds in
cities from Seattle to Boston demanded minimum-wage laws and new statutes to
support unions.
The lawmakers of the period counted on private industry
to serve as the loyal pack animal of post-war recovery. Business, they told
themselves, would pull us through in the long term. But many politicians also
believed they first had to appease voters. The modern form of appeasement —
spending — was not available to them, in part because the U.S. economy was not
the impervious superpower it is today. Nor was raising income taxes to collect
more revenue an option: The top rate was already over 70 percent.
At least, the politicians reasoned, they could placate
the public by making class war on its behalf, attacking large companies and
wealthy individuals. Perhaps capital gains, some politicians argued, ought to
be taxed heavily, at income-tax rates.
A typical conditional capitalist of the period was
Comptroller of the Currency John Skelton Williams, who ordered that banks
across the nation make public the aggregate of salaries of their executive
officers, along with the number of officers.
The country’s most important industry, railroads, had
been nationalized during the war. Keeping such industries in government hands,
some politicians told themselves, would tame the rioters. The pack animal would
go along.
It didn’t. The mixed signals from the federal and state
officials disconcerted and depressed business leaders. Some bucked like mules.
Jules S. Bache of J. S. Bache, a large investment bank, warned that “if present
conditions continue, I fear that we will have plenty of labor and plenty of
management, but that capital will disappear.” Firms even spoke of mounting a
“capital strike.”
Others raged over the treatment of capital gains. Since
the establishment of the income tax in 1913, authorities had gotten away with —
the law wasn’t especially well thought out — taxing capital gains at income-tax
rates. That hadn’t mattered when the top income-tax rate stood at its initial 7
percent, but a 73 percent capital-gains rate was another matter. The treatment
of capital gains was of course being contested. As in the case of regulation
before and after the Supreme Court’s Chevron decision,
uncertainty over the issue did its damage as well. “Every Tax Hurts” ran a
headline in the New York Sun. “Thousands upon thousands, business
men and corporations, will presently cut into their already diminished capital
to pay income and excess taxes,” pointed out the paper. “No wonder men
interested in the business of investments seize the occasion to point out the
fault of the whole system of taxes.”
Heeding such warnings, one party, the Republicans,
determined to drop the “conditional” in conditional capitalism. Where
priorities had been blurry, the 1920 GOP candidate, Warren Harding, clarified
them. “Nothing is so imperative today as efficient production and efficient
transportation,” the throaty Harding intoned. Government’s priority must be
establishing economic “normalcy” so that business could find its footing again.
In an era when papers still routinely vilified robber barons, Harding, once elected,
provocatively selected a certified plutocrat, the Pittsburgh magnate Andrew
Mellon, as Treasury secretary. Federal policy, Mellon said as he launched
“normalcy,” must remove whatever obstacles might retard the “development of
business and industry on which . . . so much of our prosperity depends.”
The part of the Harding administration’s capitalist
campaign that is best known today is the drive to cut the income tax
dramatically, from 73 percent to 30 percent or, if Harding and Mellon could
manage it, even lower. In 1921, Mellon made his first move, seeing through
Congress legislation that dropped the top income-tax rate to 53 percent. Mellon
also locked into statute a low capital-gains rate of 12.5 percent. What’s more,
Mellon even pointed out the logic of a yet lower rate, or no rate at
all: “The alternative is to refuse to recognize either capital gains or capital
losses” — not to tax them. “This is, in fact the practice which has been
followed in England for many years.” The low Mellon rate mattered, but so did
the new certainty.
But to view the exercise in tax-rate management in
isolation is to miss the larger drama of Harding’s and Mellon’s campaign. The
administration went out of its way to make clear that all taxes should
go in only one direction: downward. Closer scrutiny of the 1921 law shows that
it also punched down smaller levies that discouraged consumers and business.
“Nuisance taxes,” as they were then known, Mellon slammed as “unnecessarily
vexatious.” The 1921 law likewise removed various transportation taxes,
including a 3 percent tax on freight, a 1 percent tax on express shipments, and
an 8 percent tax on the transport of oil by pipeline. Mellon also sought to
squelch class warfare by Congress or government officials, dropping, for
example, the order that forced banks to disclose salaries.
To say that this all-out-for-business crusade met
resistance is to understate. One of the coming progressive Republicans of the
period — they had those, too — was Senator Robert M. La Follette of Wisconsin.
La Follette called for Mellon’s removal: “He is in favor of a system of
taxation that will let wealth escape.” Others threw their shoulder into
opposition as well.
“Why in the name of right and justice,” asked the minority report by Democrats of the Ways and
Means Committee of Mellon’s plans, “should these big profiteering corporations
and millionaires and multimillionaires who filled their rapacious maw with
these fabulous billions of blood money be relieved of taxation?” Nor was the
pro-business tax drive instantly popular: Republicans lost seats in both the
House and Senate in the 1922 midterms.
When Harding passed away in 1923, the new president,
Calvin Coolidge, nonetheless amped up the pro-business campaign. Nothing
captures the extent of their determination more than the “forgotten books” of
this column, the annual reports of the secretary of the Treasury from the period.
In the Revenue Act of 1924, Coolidge and Mellon managed to get the marginal tax
rate yet lower. One way or another, Mellon et al. also axed the 5- and 10-cent
taxes on telegraph and telephone messages. They brought relief to the young
soft-drink industry when they eliminated the tax on soft drinks. Other small
excise taxes levied during the war, such as those on the candy and the
motorboat industries, were now repealed. Mellon’s Treasury saw to it that yet other
taxes were reduced or limited in scope. A tax on tires and auto parts went from
5 percent to 2.5 percent. A 3 percent tax on trucks was repealed for vehicle
frames sold for $1,000 or less and for vehicle bodies sold for $200 or less.
Antitrust prosecutions, a feature of the preceding
administrations of Presidents Theodore Roosevelt, William Taft, and Woodrow
Wilson, now slowed as well.
The business response was unmistakable. Stock prices
rose, and issues of new stocks — what we now call Initial Public Offerings —
increased dramatically. What’s more, contra the 1920s reputation of being an
overheated market, scholarship by Jie Gan, Paul Mahoney, and Jianping Mei
suggests that the 1920s offerings were underpriced. As Joint Economic Committee
economist Christopher Frenze pointed out in a review of the 1920s completed in the
Reagan years, the recovery was dramatic: Manufacturing expanded 25 percent in a single year, 1922. The wealth did not
“escape” government’s clutches, to use La Follette’s image. Indeed the wealthy
shouldered a greater share of all income taxes paid than they had under
President Woodrow Wilson. Jobs proliferated, and, as important, new and better
products became available to workers. The Twenties commenced their roar.
Mellon and Coolidge did not relent. They made support for
business the centerpiece of the 1924 presidential campaign: Coolidge promised
to “bend all my energies” to get a further income-tax-rate cut. Mellon even
published a book on tax cuts to make the case to the public, Taxation: The
People’s Business. After considering running on his own, the nation’s most
important capitalist, Henry Ford, backed the Coolidge ticket, saying that the
election featured no issue “except Coolidge.”
Today, one can imagine President Trump inviting Elon
Musk, Jeff Bezos, Mark Zuckerberg, Sergey Brin, and Larry Page for a
group-photo op, though most of those fellows would surely spurn the invite.
Almost any other campaigning Republican, however, would hesitate before
publicly hosting leading billionaires. The resulting snapshot would look just
too capitalist.
Yet a hundred years ago this August, the
campaigning Coolidge hosted his era’s equivalents — Thomas Edison, Henry
Ford, and Harvey Firestone — at his birthplace and invited photographers as
well. This time, voters rewarded Coolidge and Mellon by handing Coolidge a
stunning victory — Coolidge won more votes than his two conditionally
capitalist opponents, a Democrat and the Progressive, combined. Strong
Republican majorities in the House and Senate enabled more dramatic
pro-business legislation.
Year in, year out, through 1925, 1926, and 1927, Coolidge
and Mellon sustained their pro-business push. In 1926, they even managed to cut
the income-tax rate down to 25 percent. This did not much affect the average
earner, since he did not pay income tax in those days. But that earner did
notice a stunning set of upgrades in the quality of life: the proliferation of
jobs, the spread of indoor plumbing, and the shorter workweek being three
examples.
Perhaps the most compelling symbol of the economic surge
was Henry Ford’s Model A, introduced in 1927. “New Ford Makes 70 miles Per
Hour” blared the headlines. That was quite an improvement over the 40 mph of
the old Model T.
In a 1925 speech to American newspaper editors, Coolidge
underscored his pro-business work. “The chief business of the American people
is business,” he said. That line has been mocked by progressives ever since. Of
course those same progressives fail to report that Coolidge closed his argument
with a second point, his explicit indication that he saw no contradiction
between support for business and moral behavior: “The chief ideal of the
American people is idealism.”
The takeaways here are simple. Big tax cuts and
deregulation matter. But so do little measures, the kind that scrutiny of the
data reveals. Supporting capitalism like you mean it can be a winning strategy.
Both victory and prosperity come faster when the message is wholehearted.
No comments:
Post a Comment