By Kevin D. Williamson
Wednesday, June 02, 2021
The times are frothy. The markets are frothy.
Politics is frothy. If there’s anything we have in abundance, it is froth:
The price of that isn’t going up.
Inflation really means an artificial increase
in the money supply beyond what is demanded by economic growth, though we
mostly use it to mean a general rise in consumer prices. And it is sometimes
useful to keep that distinction in mind: For example, there is some reason to
think that years of efforts at economic stimulus have, by flooding the U.S.
economy with cheap money, contributed to skyrocketing prices for assets and
commodities even while most consumer goods trucked on at their usual moderate
rate of price increase. You might not have seen much inflation at Walmart, but
you’ve seen it if you’re shopping for a house or a ton of aluminum.
The higher prices associated with inflation don’t have to
be everywhere — some prices can rise in silos, as we have seen with market
rallies and bubbles of different kinds, while other price increases put much
more intense and direct pressure on the wider economy. Fluctuations in the
price of Bitcoin are a minority concern, but when the price of a gallon of
gasoline or a pound of chicken goes up, most Americans feel it.
Traditionally, the U.S. government combats problem
inflation (meaning rapid, disruptive inflation — most economists judge a little
bit of steady inflation to be salutary, or at least unobjectionable) with
higher interest rates. In 1980, the baseline interest rate hit 20 percent as
the Federal Reserve stomped on the money supply in order to slow down inflation
that was running at 14 percent. This meant that if you wanted to take out a
mortgage to buy a house or a loan to start or expand a business, then you could
expect to pay something like 16 percent interest, as opposed to the 3 percent
you might pay on a mortgage today.
Higher interest rates can knock back inflation because
they slow down and interrupt economic activity — which might be desirable from a
macro point of view but isn’t exactly a barrel of monkeys if your business is
one of the ones that gets the pointy end of it. The market for new and used
cars is very hot right now, but try selling $50,000 Buicks with auto-finance
loans at 18 percent. Try buying — or selling — a house or a car, or building an
apartment building or expanding a factory, with loan rates at 14 percent. As
sales of cars and houses and whatnot slow down, autoworkers and builders feel
the pinch — and so do their local restaurants, shops, and service providers.
President Ronald Reagan held firm to win the fight against inflation, but if he
had been up for reelection in 1982, he’d have been slaughtered. As the deep
recession of the early 1980s showed, slowing down inflation is not a bloodless
process.
And, sometimes, it is a truly bloody mess.
The U.S. economy is complex, and the global economy into
which it is integrated is even more complex. The policymakers and central
bankers in Washington are, for the most part, smart and capable people working
with good intentions. (The truth about Washington is far more terrifying than
any conspiracy theory: The government is full of intelligent, honest, patriotic
people, and this is the best they can do.) Our economy isn’t a
lawnmower engine. Fixing any malfunctioning parts is not a straightforward
matter, and it is easy to get it wrong. In fact, it is so easy to get it wrong
that the usual working assumption in government is that policymakers are going
to get it wrong — the question is whether the policy will be catastrophically wrong
or close enough to right that everybody looks smart and the boss gets
reelected.
Consider the case of the 2008 financial crisis and the
Great Recession. Because of the 2001 recession and the economic fallout from
9/11, interest rates had been very low for years. This was an attempt to
stimulate the economy, and, like most such stimulus efforts, it produced
unintended side effects, including a bubble in the housing market. Higher
interest rates were intended to deflate that bubble and avoid what
cliché-loving economists call “overheating” the economy.
But it didn’t actually work out exactly that way: The way
in which mortgages are funded had been changing for years, and the lending boom
continued even as the Fed was tightening — until it didn’t. With interest rates
rising, millions of homeowners suddenly found themselves unable to make the
monthly payments on adjustable-rate mortgages that now far exceeded the values
of their houses, the prices of which were plunging while many could not be sold
at all. The subsequent wave of mortgage defaults far exceeded what the people
who had designed and evaluated those mortgage-backed securities had
contemplated, and poof! went
the world financial system.
That’s a hugely simplified summary, of course, but the
key points will be familiar from the vantage point of 2021: deep national
crisis, massive economic stimulus, skyrocketing prices for houses along with
other assets and commodities, and the specter of serious inflation that will,
should it manifest, demand serious action from the Fed and other policymakers.
How might that shake out? The lesson from the financial
crisis is: Nobody really knows.
What joins inflation and interest rates is the issue of
risk. You charge interest on a loan because there is risk involved when you let
someone else use your money: For instance, the borrower might not pay you back,
or a lovely investment opportunity might be dropped into your lap at a moment
when you cannot benefit from it because your money is tied up somewhere else.
Inflation is another such risk: If there is high inflation, then you may lose
money on the loan in real terms even if it is paid back in full with the
agreed-upon interest.
Because inflation erodes the value of a dollar — meaning
that the dollars you get paid back with tomorrow will be less valuable than the
dollars you lent today — the real rate of return on an
investment is the return after inflation. (When you read about real GDP
or real incomes, that’s what they’re talking about — GDP or
incomes or whatever adjusted for inflation.) Sometimes, the problem of
inflation is addressed by avoiding some risk, as in the case
of inflation-indexed bonds, which pay interest at a rate that includes
inflation, whatever it turns out to be over the term of the bond. But at other
times, the problem of inflation is addressed by seeking out more risk,
with investors forced to seek higher returns to offset inflation or lose ground
in real terms.
The Austrian school of economics blames recessions and
much economic unhappiness on artificially low borrowing costs. Austrians call
it “malinvestment,” by which they mean that a whole lot of loans, business
plans, and personal financial decisions that looked smart when interest rates
were low do not look smart when interest rates are high. According to this
model, artificially cheap money lures investors into making bad investments
that will unravel once reality reasserts itself, as it always does, and a recession
is what happens while that’s getting sorted out and capital is being shifted
from unprofitable investments into profitable ones. The problem, from this
point of view, isn’t the bust — it’s the boom.
There is something to that. Republicans have traditionally
been allied with the business lobby, which generally cheers low interest rates
and easy money and tries to keep the party going as long as possible. But a
genuinely conservative economic policy would address risk and
complexity in the only reliable way we know how: by being careful with both
borrowing and lending, by paying close attention to both sides of the
taxing-and-spending equation, by exercising thrift, prudence, and restraint.
Commodities prices at the moment are, as they say, frothy.
That doesn’t mean policy can or should be frothy, too — we can’t afford it to
be, even if that isn’t immediately obvious.
No comments:
Post a Comment