By Kevin D. Williamson
Tuesday, January 08, 2019
We don’t talk about the United Fruit Company as much as
we used to. I miss that.
In the Eighties and Nineties, a conservative arguing with
a progressive about practically anything had at his disposal a very handy
heuristic: “Oh, yeah? Well what about the United Fruit Company in Guatemala?”
If a left-leaning interlocutor went fruity within the first five minutes of a
conversation that was not about Guatemala, bananas, or anything very closely
related, then you knew he was a kook. Or, to put it more charitably, that he
was not likely to prove persuadable by reason and facts.
“What about the United Fruit Company in Guatemala?” was
my generation’s version of the old joke from the Soviet Union:
A Soviet official is proudly
showing an impressive Moscow subway station to an American engineer. The
visitor is so enchanted that he lingers for quite a time — during which no
trains pass through. When he asks, “But where are the trains?” the Russian
indignantly replies, “What about the Negroes in the South?”
The libertarian economist Tyler Cowen has helped to
popularize the idea that ideology is at least partly about status — about the desire to see certain social groups rise or fall
in their relative status rankings. People on the left who think of themselves
as the “smart people and the virtuous people” resent the relatively high status
of the people with a lot of money, and they organize their beliefs around
lowering the status of that class. That helps to explain certain
irrationalities one sees among progressives, i.e. their preference for policies
that punish the wealthy for being wealthy over policies that help very poor
people, their focus on “inequality” over absolute standards of living, etc. But
it is only financial inequality that annoys them; other kinds of inequality,
for instance inequality in intelligence or in academic achievement, receive
less attention because they do not contribute to the progressives’ feelings of
status envy.
The English philosopher Michael Oakeshott argued that
ideological disputes are, “in the strict sense, preposterous,” because
ideologies are intellectual back-formations: “Far from a political ideology
being the quasi-divine parent of political activity, it turns out to be its
earthly stepchild,” he argues. “Instead of an independently premeditated scheme
of ends to be pursued, it is a system of ideas abstracted from the manner in
which people have been accustomed to go about the business of attending to the
arrangements of their societies. The pedigree of every political ideology shows
it to be the creature, not of premeditation in advance of political activity,
but of meditation upon a manner of politics. In short, political activity comes
first and a political ideology follows after.”
That’s what the United Fruit Company rhetorical scheme is
all about: It’s a way of rhetorically putting capitalism in its place by
putting capitalists in their place. If anything, Professor Cowen and those who
share his view may underestimate how much political ideology is, outside of
professional and semiprofessional academic circles, a status game. Consider our
current political discourse (which is the subject of my upcoming book) and the
means by which it is conducted: Status is a stock, and social media is the
platform for high-frequency trading in the status market.
I thought of the United Fruit Company when reading my friend
J. D. Vance’s contribution to National
Review’s very interesting in-house debate about the themes brought up by
Tucker Carlson’s now-famous monologue, in which he argues that conservatives
have been too deferential to commercial interests at the expense of the
national interest. Vance offers an argument in a familiar mode: indictment. What about the
pharmaceutical companies that make those opioids that so many Americans abuse?
What about Apple having its Chinese operations knuckle under to Beijing? What
about the marijuana producers pushing for broader legalization of their
product?
So, then: What about those? It is true that the managers
of businesses break the law like anybody else, and that they exploit such
political and regulatory advantages as they can identify. And we prosecute them
for law-breaking, though maybe not as much as we should, e.g., in the case of
those who employ illegal aliens. One need not accept the vulgar “realism” of
the fiduciary defense — the moral dodge that business executives have a
positive moral obligation to be as ruthless as legally possible in pursuit of
their shareholders’ financial interests — to wonder at the relevance of this
assertion. Vance argues that pharmaceutical companies were not entirely
forthcoming in their dealings with the Food and Drug Administration. Count me
among those who are not very much surprised by this. But is it really the case
that what the hillbillies he writes about need is an FDA with a heavier hand?
How did that work out the last time we tried it? If memory serves, the federal
effort to constrict the pharmaceutical opioid market was associated with an
increase in the consumption of heroin.
I am open to the argument that we need a more intrusive
regime of pharmaceutical regulation. If J. D. Vance wants to make that case,
then he should make that case.
If, on the other hand, his project here — like Tucker
Carlson’s sneering that the Republican agenda is to “make the world safe for
banking” — is simply to adopt a rhetoric that lowers the status of a group that
seems to him to get its way too often (and it seems to me that is what he is
doing here, intentionally or not), then it almost certainly is not going to
produce anything useful in terms of proposals for reform. In my back-and-forth
with Michael Brendan Dougherty some time ago about his “Garbutt” thought
experiment, I was frustrated by the same mushiness: Even assuming that all of
Dougherty’s fine-tuning of the moral standing and status of his various
subjects is carried out with superhuman accuracy: What then? What is it our
gentle new breed of nationalists would like to see done?
Because if the problem we are trying to address is the
situation of low-income, unemployed, and marginally employed white men in rural
and semi-rural areas, none of the tut-tutting about the moral failings of this
or that business leader in New York City or Palo Alto changes the fact that we have
two choices: We help these men to become self-sufficient, or we maintain them
in welfare dependency indefinitely. As Jim Geraghty points out in his
contribution to the debate, there are thousands and thousands of manufacturing
jobs going unfilled around the country. It seems to me that the most promising
social policy would be one that seeks to connect those men with those jobs. A
ham-fisted trade war with China is not the most obvious way to go about doing that.
Responding to Ben Shapiro’s observation that the spread
of global capitalism had led to measurable positive outcomes around the world,
Vance writes: “Our economy has not produced fewer dead children and more living
parents in America, at least not in the section of the country where I live.” But
the more direct and obvious conclusion of that observation is that the local
conditions Vance writes about are largely independent of market capitalism. If
the same market forces that are coincident with longer and happier lives abroad
are present in the communities Vance writes about, isn’t the more reasonable
conclusion that the dysfunction is in those communities rather than in
“capitalism,” however amorphously defined?
What evidence is there, if any, that it is our economy that produces the horrors that
Vance describes so eloquently? The United States and El Salvador have about the
same suicide rate; so do the United States and Finland. So do Belgium and
India. So do Japan and Burkina Faso. Desperately poor Yemen has a suicide rate
about one-third that of Russia, which is governed by economic nationalists
much-admired by some in the American nationalist-populist camp. What should
this tell us about the relationship between economic policy at the broad level
and social dysfunction?
The critique of free trade and free markets offered by
the nationalist-populist Right lacks intellectual rigor. Most of the time, it
is an argument put forward with approximately the depth of the All in the Family theme song:
Guys like us we had it made,
Those were the days,
And you know where you were then,
Girls were girls and men were men,
Mister we could use a man like
Herbert Hoover again.
The difference is, Archie Bunker sang that he “didn’t
need no welfare state,” whereas his spiritual heirs frequently argue that we do
not have one that is sufficient.
The nationalist critique also lacks much of anything that
could charitably be described as an intelligent and plausible policy agenda.
The actual agenda of the Trump administration has been a lot like the actual
agenda of the Republican party for years: a conventional tax-reform bill,
judges recommended by the Federalist Society, regulatory reform, etc. How the
renegotiation of NAFTA is going to improve the lives of people afflicted by
unemployment is not obvious.
Which deepens my suspicion that this is not a policy
debate at all, but a status game. Certain people are thriving under
globalization, certain people are not, we understand the losers as “our
people,” and the outcome of this is ressentiment.
Critiques that reduce the status of the winners are preferred to those that
reduce the status of the losers. Toeing that line can lead to ridiculous
outcomes, e.g. trying somehow to connect Bain Capital’s earnings to heroin
overdoses in Arkansas.
Which brings me to Tucker Carlson’s monologue. I like and
respect Tucker enormously, and have long admired him very much as a writer.
That being said, his monologue was insipid, albeit insipid in the way that
practically everything comparable on cable-news opinion shows is insipid. As
Geraghty already has pointed out, it was full of plain factual errors — it
simply is not the case the manufacturing has disappeared from the American economy
— and its occasional descent into Starship
Troopers–style propagandizing does not give me much hope for things to
come. Mitt Romney in stark black-and-white over a Bain Capital sign, Tucker
Carlson with the American flag projected behind him: I cannot imagine how a man
of Tucker Carlson’s wit and intelligence participates in such risible pageantry
without being embarrassed to death.
Tucker Carlson says that conservatives are operating with
blinders, that “the idea that families are being crushed by market forces never
seems to occur to them.” Perhaps it is the case that the possibility has
occurred to them, and that the proposition has been examined and found to be
untrue. Carlson mocks the idea that lower prices for consumer goods — “plastic
garbage from China,” in the popular banal formulation — are in the interests of
Americans of more modest means; I would like to suggest, in all charity and
friendship, that those Americans who are literally counting their pennies could
do with hearing a good deal less about the triviality of low prices from a
born-rich multimillionaire who never had to literally count pennies. If you
have ever known a family who — and this is a real-life example — used to dread
receiving Christmas presents because they could not afford the postage to send
a thank-you note, then you know what lower prices can mean to real people.
Which brings me to the obvious point of inquiry: What do
the nationalists have to offer that is of more value than those lower prices?
Vance writes that when it comes to the problems of people
in his community, we are told “we can’t talk about them, because it promotes
victimhood.” Told by whom? Which
problems are we not talking about? Opioid
abuse? Unemployment
and intergenerational poverty? Lack
of agency? I am reminded of those claims that “We need to have a national
conversation about x,” where x is one of those things that we never stop having a national conversation
about.
I will get into this at greater length in my book, but
Tucker Carlson’s argument that the state’s job is to see to our happiness, rather than to see to public
order, represents a return to a political primitivism associated with the
medieval period, when everyone, peasant and lord alike, knew his place and
could be sure of his role in this kingdom and in the Heavenly Kingdom, a
clockwork universe in which the great majority of people may have been
miserable in absolute material terms but in which they had confidence in the
fixity of the social order, and hence in the security of their own status. The
emergence of primitive capitalism disrupted that order, and the emergence of
global capitalism has, in a similar way, disrupted the postwar American social
order.
As Yuval Levin and others have argued, it is nostalgia
for that order — or our mythologized misrecollection of it — that animates much
of the politics of our time, especially the frustrated and fearful populism
whose partisans do not seem to understand that they can have a 1957 standard of
living any time they choose, and that it can be had on the cheap.
No comments:
Post a Comment