By Kevin D. Williamson
Monday November 27, 2023
In a recent episode of The Remnant, Jonah
Goldberg referred to our mutual friend Charles C.W. Cooke of National
Review as a “Roundhead.” By this he meant to indicate that Charlie is
of English background, which is one way to distinguish him from the e-less
Charlie Cook who writes the Cook Political Report. There are a lot
of Charlie Cooks out there, as it turns out—another Charlie Cook writes
cookbooks, meaning that these cookbooks are Cook books—and so some
disambiguation is necessary at times. But there is another sense in which my
onetime podcasting partner is a “Roundhead,” one that I hope catches on and
spreads: He is what would have been known as a “Parliamentarian” during the
English Civil Wars, a partisan of the legislative branch over the executive. In
the American context, that makes him what is sometimes known as a “congressional
supremacist.”
(The Roundheads were called that because their ranks were
dominated by Puritans who wore their hair short, in contrast to the flowing
locks of the monarchical Cavaliers. At least, that’s the story: In reality,
English political coiffure turns out to be more complicated. Our Charlie does
not sport a Puritan buzz cut. Also, Charlie is an atheist rather than a member
of the Church of England, which, from my Catholic point of view, doesn’t seem
like that big a difference, but, apparently, the Puritans cared a great deal
about that sort of thing.)
There are two schools of thought about the relative
powers of the three branches into which our federal government is divided. One
is the theory of “coequal branches,” which holds that the executive, the
legislative, and the judicial branches are equal in status and in power, and
that none is subordinate to the others. The idea of coequal branches fortifies
the principle of separation of powers—how can powers be truly separated if the
three branches are not mutually independent of one another? But if the idea of
coequal branches comports well with the theory of how our constitutional order
is supposed to work, congressional supremacy is more in accord with the actual
text of the Constitution. We do not need to read too much into the fact that
setting up the legislative branch is the Constitution’s first order of business
(Article I) but we do need to understand the Constitution invests a very mighty
share of national governing power in Congress compared to the other two
branches—and why it does that.
The president may have a good deal of independent
discretion in conducting foreign policy, but only Congress can declare war or
ratify a treaty. High-level executive appointments require the consent of the
Senate, but no legislative office is subject to the endorsement of another
branch. The president can veto a bill, but Congress can override that veto and
has the final say. Congress can remove a president, a Supreme Court justice, or
any federal officer through impeachment, but no member of the executive or
judicial branch has the power to remove a member of Congress. Congress has the
power to make “exceptions” and “regulations” regarding the Supreme Court’s
appellate jurisdiction. Congress holds all taxing and spending authority. So
sure, the branches are coequal, except for Congress’ predominant role in … war,
peace, treaties, taxes, spending, confirming high-level personnel, removing
problem federal officers up to and including presidents, and—what else was
there? Oh, yes—writing all the laws.
The practical supremacy of Congress in our constitutional
order is one of those truths that would seem to be self-evident. But I’ll bet
most of you don’t know off the top of your head who the chairman of the Senate
Foreign Relations Committee is—and, being Dispatch readers,
you are probably in the top 1 or 2 percent in terms of being well-informed
about these kinds of things. On the other hand, most of you know who the third-
and fourth-place contenders for the 2024 Republican presidential nomination
are. I recently was on a flight out of Dallas with former New Jersey Gov. Chris
Christie, and lots of people in the airport recognized him and wanted to talk.
Christie is a very approachable and gregarious guy; it is easy to see why he
has had a successful career in politics. But he is not going to be the
Republican nominee in 2024, and he is not going to be president. Nonetheless,
he is a political celebrity; on the other hand, an important legislator such as
John Barrasso (the Senate Republican conference chairman) could walk around DFW
all day without anybody taking notice—he’s just another guy peering into his
laptop at the Centurion Lounge.
I have a literary/cinematic theory of American politics.
As writers of thriller novels or action movies will advise you, the easiest way
to keep the audience’s attention is to make sure that the hero is present in as
many scenes as possible; and, where the hero is not present, the main villain
or monster should be at center stage. You saw this in the film
noir classics, which were heavily influenced by hardboiled detective
fiction such as the novels of Mickey Spillane and his Prohibition-era
antecedents, where the protagonist was present in every scene because the story
was almost invariably told in his voice and from his point of view. In the
United States, we have 435 members of the House of Representatives, 100
senators, nine Supreme Court justices and 861 other Article III judges, 25
Cabinet members (26 if you count the vice president, which, sure),
194 ambassadors, etc.—and one president. Good stories may lean on a heroic
narrative arc, but good government looks a lot more like an endless series of
committee meetings. When it comes to Americans’ political engagement, we have
become something a lot less like active citizens and something a lot more
accurately described as content consumers—and the content we prefer
to consume is heroic, action-movie stuff. That works both ways: There have been
a lot of action movies featuring U.S. presidents as action heroes (Air Force
One, etc.) but not a whole lot focused on the ranking member of the House
Ways and Means Committee.
Another way of saying this is that we have a tendency
toward monarchy in the most literal sense of the word—mono-archy,
with the state’s power effectively invested in one man. Kingship speaks to
something deep in us as a species: The institution of one-man rule, or some
near variation of it, is far too widespread across cultures and times to be a
matter of mere political innovation. When the Romans slid from republic to
principate, they were not really creating something new—they were reverting to
something old. The Romans, of course, knew that, which is why they did not call
their new old-fashioned headmen kings, rex being a
kind of dirty word in Latin. No self-respecting Roman would deign to live under
a king—but a commander in chief is another story!
The Latin word for commander in chief is imperator, from which our
English emperor is derived. The humble fish once known
as slimehead was rebranded orange roughy as
it made its way to fancy dinner plates, but, call it what you will, it still
stinks after three days. Whatever you call the mono in your
monarchy, it is the fact of the mono, not the label you put on it,
that really matters.
Relatively few people say they support one-man rule, and
relatively few people say that they think one-man rule is a good form of
government. Even the real-deal monarchists among us are mostly monarchists on
the Anglo-European model, advocates of constitutional monarchies with
parliaments exercising most of the real political power. People and peoples
fall into strongman government—into monarchism or caudillo-ism or
dictatorship—simply by following the bouncing ball. A single point of focus, in
motion, easily commands the eye, and, the eye being conquered, the heart and
mind soon follow. In one of the other very quotable scenes from A Man
for All Seasons, an exasperated Henry VIII limns the political currents of
his regime: “There are those like Norfolk who follow me because I wear the
crown; and those like Master Cromwell who follow me because they are jackals
with sharp teeth and I’m their tiger; there’s a mass that follows me because it
follows anything that moves.”
The president moves.
Congress moves, too, but it moves very slowly, and its
locomotion is crablike, sideways. The legislative branch does not stride
forward in a heroic fashion. It isn’t supposed to, of course, and it would be
bad if it did—but the public eye is always hungry for a hero. That is a failure
of republican—note the lowercase “r” there—self-respect. Citizens are supposed
to be the heroes of republican government, but we aren’t, probably because we
do not feel that we are able to play the heroic role, the forces that rule our
world being so complex and inscrutable: viruses that are too small to see,
global markets that are too big to see. I do not think that Daniel Patrick
Moynihan’s many decades spent trying to make our laws a little better were any
less well-spent than Horatius’ lonesome stand at the bridge, but nobody will
write any epic poems about the Moynihan
Report.
Heroic politics is almost always bad politics—it is how
you get demagogues, dictators, and emperors. It is also how you end up with
so-called conservatives cheering for the prospect of a demagogue, dictator, or
emperor—or, short of that, offering hilariously
limp apologia for those who do dream of such things.
Thomas Jefferson’s political organ came to be known as
the Republican Party (which, confusingly, is the forebear of the modern
Democratic Party rather than of the modern party that bears the same name)
because its leaders hoped to act on a republican agenda—and there is more to
being a republic than simply not being a monarchy. The Jeffersonian Republicans
(the label “Democratic-Republican Party” is a historians’ convenience) opposed
what they saw as the covert monarchism of George Washington and John Adams as
well as the imperialism and nationalism of the Federalists and the so-called
American System. And no less significant, they bristled at what they saw as the
aristocratic pretensions of their political rivals. Jeffersonian Republicans
were against the centralization of power in the national government, and
detested the homogenizing effects of that centralization. They argued for a
smaller federal government and, for a while, even delivered it, with the
Jefferson administration and its congressional allies lowering federal spending
and reducing the national debt.
But beyond less debt and lower spending, what
republicanism requires—in our time no less than theirs—is an expansive and
active conception of citizenship and an arrangement of government that puts
power in the places where it is closest to those citizens: in the Congress
(and, especially, in the House) at the federal level, and in the state
legislatures rather than in the federal machine. This isn’t exactly a democratic argument,
in that it would be better to move power from the executive back to Congress
even if we still had senators who were not directly elected (a man can dream!)
and even if the fortification of non-elected institutions (especially the
political parties) resulted in a system that was less strictly democratic, less
majoritarian, and less responsive to elections—and especially less responsive
to primary elections. In any kind of representative government (and in many
kinds of non-representative government), government will be dominated by those
who show up. A big idea of citizenship means one in which there are lots of
ways to show up—ways well beyond simply showing up to vote in years in which
there is a presidential election.
It is not a bad thing that there are people who serve for
many decades in Congress or in other government offices. But having more people
who are not—dread words!—career politicians rotating through the
state legislatures and the Congress might be a good thing, too: It is not as
though we cannot have both, a mix of long-term institutionalists and highly
focused short-term reformers and single-issue advocates. But none of that is
going to matter very much if we continue slipping into a kind of soft
principate, with the president bestriding the political world like … whatever
imitation of a Colossus that Joe Biden or Donald Trump can manage.
What does that mean, practically? It means regular order,
with Congress making appropriations in the correct constitutional way rather
than running the country on an endlessly ad hoc basis through
emergency funding mechanisms and omnibus bills. It means less congressional
deference to presidents—especially when the president is a member of the same
party as the congressional majority. It means no more regulatory enabling acts,
open-ended delegations of power from the legislative to the executive, as in
the grievously misnamed Affordable Care Act. It means no more open-ended
authorizations for the use of military force. It means less executive
imperialism within Congress, too, a turn away from the Nancy Pelosi model of
what amounts to a speaker’s dictatorship within the House—with legislation
exnihilated into being by the leadership and then subjected to an up-or-down
vote with very little debate or discussion—and back toward the old, cumbrous,
and excruciatingly boring mode of lawmaking, with its hearings
and fact-finding and negotiations, all the embarrassing business of making
law in public.
But a republic is a public thing.
Economics for English Majors
A very useful concept from economics just now is substitution.
How do you know if one product is a substitute for another? Generally speaking,
products are substitutes if demand for one increases when the price of the
other goes up. Some substitutes are obvious: If Nike athletic shoes and Reebok
athletic shoes are functionally pretty much the same thing, then we would
expect to see demand for Reeboks go up when Nike prices rise. If that isn’t the
case—and it often is not the case for very brand-driven products such as
sneakers—then that suggests that the products are not very good substitutes
even though they are functionally identical because it is not the function that
sells the shoe but the brand or some other factor.
When new-car prices spiked to record highs in the
post-COVID-19 period and kept going up, demand for used cars went up—and,
since there was no commensurate increase in supply, prices for used cars went
up, too. Used-car prices have for a long time moved roughly in tandem with
new-car prices, which suggests that, for many buyers, used cars are a pretty
good substitute for new cars. Prices and consumption levels also suggest that
two of the things that our progressive friends push as substitutes for
old-fashioned petroleum-powered cars—electric vehicles and mass
transit—probably are not very good substitutes, at least for a great many
buyers. Car prices are much higher today than they were before the pandemic,
but mass-transit usage is lower, having bounced back and apparently plateaued
at about 80
percent of pre-COVID usage. That’s interesting in that it holds true even
in many places where mass transit is massively subsidized or offered at no
point-of-use cost to riders. Electric vehicles remain a very small part of the
overall U.S. market for cars, SUVs, and light-duty trucks (less than 1 percent
of overall vehicle sales, according
to J.D. Power), and demand for EVs does not seem to correspond very closely
to fluctuations in petroleum prices. I happen to like some EVs and think they
are a good choice for most drivers, but, the thing about markets is, everybody
gets a say.
Some of this stuff requires looking at the issue from a
couple of steps back. One of the reasons you don’t see people abandoning cars
for mass transit, for example, is that housing along the most desirable
mass-transit corridors tends to be expensive (see Philadelphia’s Main Line or
the New York area’s Metro North), while the most price-sensitive commuters will
(in many areas) be the ones who have the least ready access to good transit
options. That we make it so difficult to build affordable housing in so many
places produces results that naturally show up in markets beyond housing. In
that sense, progressives trying to get more people to use mass transit aren’t
really just telling commuters that they need to drive less—they are telling
them that they need to get a home in Stamford or Villanova or Boston’s West
End.
Periods of high inflation are not much fun for anybody,
but rising prices do help reveal substitutes. As it turns out, there are lots
of substitutes for products in the apparel and electronics markets, but, as you
might have guessed, not for baby formula.
Words About Words
As a reader points out, “revert back” is a redundancy; as
with the dreaded “advocate for,” the preposition is unnecessary, because it is
right there in the word itself: re- in revert,
and ad- in advocate. Because we need a redundant
word for redundancy, these fall into the category of things known
as pleonasms. Some pleonasms are idiomatic (safe haven, eye
witness, added bonus) and some are used for rhetorical effect (I
saw it with my own eyes). But, sometimes, they are just clumsy writing or
clumsy thinking. It isn’t always better to use as few words as possible
(according to the guy who writes 121-word opening sentences), but economy is
generally desirable. And if you are going to write irritating little things
like “revert back,” you’d better be doing it on purpose, for effect.
In Closing
As you may know, there has been some debate over the
years about how to write the word we commonly use for the hatred of Jews: anti-Semitism?
anti-semitism? antisemitism? Etc. There is even some question about
whether we should use the word at all: Like ethnic cleansing, it is
a kind of euphemism, popularized as a scientific-sounding replacement for the
German Judenhass. I myself have long preferred “Jew-hating
weirdo” or other designations along those lines, which, unfortunately, seems a
little lighthearted for the current moment. Old-school Jew-hatred is back in
the news—and back in our inboxes, I’m afraid—with the familiar cretins playing
the greatest hits: The Rothschilds secretly run the world! The Jews are the
“synagogue of Satan”! etc. Without downplaying the ugliness and the
potential danger of this moment, it is worth remembering that this stuff has
been around forever. Someone forwarded me a “political newsletter” from a
crackpot dilettante that hit all the familiar themes, and it was more or less
indistinguishable from the conspiracy mimeographs and faxes that went around in
the 1980s and 1990s. This kind of thing has been around for a very long time,
but great age has not conferred any respectability on it. It is like syphilis,
which first emerged in human populations around 3000 B.C.—an apparently
ineradicable part of the human condition, an infection of the brain.
No comments:
Post a Comment