By David Hogberg
Thursday, July 30, 2015
As Wednesday was Medicare’s 50th anniversary, many on the
left are celebrating by pushing a single-payer system they dub
“Medicare-for-All.” Former Labor Secretary Robert Reich got an early start by
publishing a piece the other day in Newsweek (yes, it still exists), claiming
that, “Medicare isn’t the problem. It’s the solution.” The answer, he says,
“isn’t to shrink Medicare. It’s to grow it—allowing anyone at any age to join.”
The article is a mix of misleading “facts” and
incoherency, so let’s have some fun with it, starting with Reich’s silliest
argument:
Medicare’s administrative costs are in the range of 3 percent. That’s well below the 5 to 10 percent costs borne by large companies that self-insure. It’s even further below the administrative costs of companies in the small-group market (amounting to 25 to 27 percent of premiums).
Comparing government administrative costs with private
sector ones is usually an apple-to-oranges comparison, and Michael Cannon of the
Cato Institute has a great criticism of the argument that Medicare is more
efficient because it has lower administrative costs here.
To make this simple, let’s apply that logic to other
areas of the government. It’s quite possible that Amtrak has lower
administrative costs than Georgia Southwestern, and the Post Office’s Priority
Mail Service has lower administrative costs than Federal Express. I’ll wait for
Reich to argue that freight rail and overnight delivery would be more efficient
if run by the government, but I won’t hold my breath waiting.
Next, Reich argues that, “Medicare continues to be blamed
for America’s present and future budget problems. That’s baloney.”
Was it just my imagination, or did the recent Medicare
Trustees Report say that the “present value” unfunded liability of Medicare
over the next 75 years is about $41 trillion? A little closer in time, the
Congressional Budget Office numbers show that, net of interest payments, 1 in 5
dollars of the federal budget will be spent on Medicare by 2029. By 2041 it
will be almost 1 in 4 dollars. Reich doesn’t address any of this “baloney.”
No argument for Medicare-for-All is complete without an
erroneous comparison of the U.S. health care system to the rest of the world:
Americans spend more on health care per person than any other advanced nation and get less for our money. […] The typical American lives 78.1 years—less than the average 80.1 years in other advanced nations. And we have the highest rate of infant mortality of all advanced nations.
Using life expectancy and infant mortality to measure the
performance of a health care system is like using batting average and on-base
percentage to judge football. Life expectancy is influenced by many factors
such as per-capita wealth, sanitation, diet, and so forth that a health care
system has little, if any, control over. Not only is infant mortality
influenced by those same factors, it is measured inconsistently across nations.
For example, in Canada, Germany, and Austria, a baby born weighing less than
500 grams is not counted as a live birth as it is in the U.S. That, obviously,
makes their infant mortality statistics look much better than ours.
Reich next examines why our health care system has so
many deaths due to medical errors:
One big reason is we keep patient records on computers that can’t share the data. Patient records are continuously re-written and then re-entered into different computers. That leads to lots of mistakes.
Funny that he doesn’t say what Medicare can do to solve
this. Since 2009, Medicare has had an Electronic Health Record (EHR) Meaningful
Use incentive program through which physicians can receive $44,000 to switch to
EHRs. It’s working out pretty much as you might expect. A poll from early last
year found that 70 percent of physicians say EHRs have not been worth the cost.
Despite the subsidies from Medicare and from a similar program in Medicaid,
problems abound:
Some physicians say it’s not nearly enough to cover the increasing costs of implementation, training, annual licensing fees, hardware and associated services. But the most dramatic unanticipated costs were associated with the need to increase staff, coupled with a loss in physician productivity.
‘We used to see 32 patients a day with one tech, and now
we struggle to see 24 patients a day with four techs. And we provide worse
care,’ said one survey respondent.
Finally, Reich complains that health care “costs continue
to rise because doctors and hospitals still spend too much money on unnecessary
tests, drugs and procedures.” Hospital and physicians order costly MRIs and
then do back surgery. Physical therapy would be just as effective, but it
“doesn’t generate much revenue.” If you seek treatment for diabetes, asthma or
a heart condition in the hospital, Reich says: “20 percent of the time you’re
back within a month.”
It would be far less costly if a nurse visited you at
home to make sure you were taking your medications, a common practice in other
advanced nations. But nurses don’t do home visits to Americans with acute
conditions because hospitals aren’t paid for them.
Gee, is it possible that Medicare has something to do
with this? Maybe, just maybe, as medicine evolves and providers find better and
more efficient ways to treat patients, a sluggish bureaucracy like Medicare
isn’t particularly good at updating what it pays for.
And what is Reich’s solution to this? As he states at the
beginning of the article, “Medicare offers a way to reduce these underlying
costs—if Washington would let it.”
I can see it now: You are slapping your forehead, exclaiming,
“If Washington would let it! Why didn’t I think of that?!”
Well, Washington won’t let Medicare make such changes
because it is filled with groups such as hospital and physician associations
that have a vested interest in keeping a cash cow like Medicare largely the way
it is. Those vested interests don’t care for the competition that would arise
if Medicare started changing what it paid for.
That problem would only be exacerbated if Congress opened
up Medicare to everyone. Treatment under Medicare wouldn’t necessarily be
determined by what was best for the patient but by who had sufficient political
power to influence Congress on Medicare policy.
As I argue in my new book, Medicare’s Victims, it is
often the sickest patients who suffer the most under Medicare because they are
the most likely to lack political power. Consider the Medicare patients who, as
Reich complains, have to return to the hospital 20 percent of the time. There
are probably too few of them to have much impact on Congressional elections,
one of the most important ways of influencing Congress. Additionally, many of
them may be quite ill and thus in no condition to be organizing, protesting,
getting media coverage and other things that can get the attention of Congress
to change Medicare policy.
Those with political power would get good care, while
those without such power—often the sickest—would lose out. That would be the
nightmare result if Reich’s dream ever became a reality.
No comments:
Post a Comment