By Kevin D. Williamson
Monday, July 07, 2014
To repurpose Willi Schlamm, the problem with science is
scientists. In the current issue of National Review, Charles C. W. Cooke has a
pitiless essay on the cult of Neil deGrasse Tyson and “America’s nerd problem,”
and in the prior issue I touched on a similar subject, the meme-ification of
science for political purposes, in “Nobody @#$%&*! Loves Science.” The
common theme is prestige: Science enjoys enormous public esteem, which it has
earned for itself, and it is inevitable that political types seek to bask in
that prestige themselves, or to dress their policy preferences in white lab
coats. Thus the MSNBC humble-braggadocio about being “nerds” — Neil deGrasse
Tyson and Chris Hayes being fellow nerds in the same sense that Buzz Aldrin and
those monkeys were fellow astronauts.
The problem is that scientific prestige accompanies
scientists well outside their fields of expertise. That’s true when they wander
into other scientific fields — as I noted in my essay, Carl Sagan authored
scientific illiteracies based on long-discredited ideas in the course of
arguing for abortion — but the problem is most acute when it comes to the
matter of politics. A relatively recent and intensely annoying example of this
comes from my alma mater, the University of Texas, which is proud to employ the
physicist Steven Weinberg, who was awarded the Nobel prize in 1979. Professor
Weinberg is not short of opinions — evangelizing for causes ranging from
atheism to Zionism — and is unsurprisingly interested in the question of
government funding for scientific research, a subject he explores in his
compact essay “The Crisis in Big Science,” recently republished in The Best
American Science and Nature Writing of 2013. (Yes, I am a little behind on my
reading; I also have 54,000 unread e-mails.) Professor Weinberg’s essay is
remarkably simple-minded, though it is admirably modest: Offering a potted
history of the Standard Model, he mentions the unification of the weak and
electromagnetic forces but not the fact that he is one of the men who did that.
I do not get the impression that Professor Weinberg is
the grasping sort, but it is worth noting that the man arguing that we need to
spend more money not only on science but on most everything government does —
he endorses a general increase in tax rates and an equally general expansion of
the state — is a 1 percenter among public dependents. More than that: He was,
as of 2012, the ninth most highly paid professor in these United States,
annually taking home the equivalent of Berkshire Hathaway CEO Warren Buffett’s
salary plus Morningstar CEO Joe Mansueto’s salary. His wife is paid an
additional quarter-million a year as a tenured professor at the University of
Texas law school (the reputation of which is in dramatic decline of late). Some
years ago, an administrator at the University of Texas described Professor
Weinberg’s professional responsibilities to me in approximately these words:
“He has a Nobel prize; he does what he wants.” The Weinberg household is a very
significant net recipient of tax dollars. That being written, he seems to be a
very productive man, and UT has spent a great deal more money on much less
admirable investments: Mack Brown, who led the Longhorns to mediocrity on the
gridiron, was paid approximately ten times what Professor Weinberg is.
Before I go on, I should note that my objection to
Professor Weinberg’s essay is the stupidity and crudeness of its argument; I
largely agree with his position about funding ambitious science. In fact, it is
because I agree with his position on Big Science that the rest of his essay
vexes me. His good point is wrapped in a wrongheaded and poisonous generality;
it’s like serving an ice-cream sundae in a bowl shaped like Andrew Cuomo’s
face.
Just as Austin spends on far less worthy endeavors than
physicists, Washington spends on far less worthy projects than the fundamental
infrastructure necessary to their work, such as particle accelerators and
space-based telescopes. These are large projects, fiscally and physically —
Switzerland’s Large Hadron Collider at CERN spills over into France — sometimes
beyond the carrying capacity of anything short of a national government or a
consortium of them. It was in fact the frustrating fight over the
Superconducting Super Collider (SSC) that first brought me into contact with
Professor Weinberg; he was an energetic advocate for the project, and I was
writing about it for my college newspaper. The SSC was a project dear to UT’s
heart, as it was under the direction of a member of its physics department, Roy
Schwitters, and was to be built in Texas. Professor Weinberg relates a very
Washingtonian story about the debacle, in which he is advised that before the
site selection, the SSC had 100 supporters in the Senate, but after the site
selection it could expect to have two. That is approximately what happened. The
project, begun under Republican governor Bill Clements and President Ronald
Reagan, was torpedoed by Ann Richards and House Democrats, with a largely
uninterested Bill Clinton attempting to intervene on the project’s behalf at
the last minute, and then signing its death warrant a few months later. The
site in Waxahachie, with its 15 miles of tunnel, is a monument to how politics
works.
Professor Weinberg understands the defects of the
political system when it comes to the management of substantial scientific
projects, but he proposing expanding the scope of that defective system — not
only in regard to politics, but categorically. He offers us no reason to
believe that we should expect different results from doing precisely the same
thing — the very definition of insanity misattributed to Albert Einstein. (The
actual source seems to have been a Narcotics Anonymous book, but scientists
enjoy more prestige than do recovering drug addicts, which is why Steven
Weinberg’s public-policy thoughts get published and those of your equally
well-informed Uncle Roscoe do not.) As he notes, one of the reasons that
projects such as the SSC end up exceeding their cost estimates is that Congress
slow-walks appropriations to them, dragging out the process and adding to
time-related expenses, which in construction can be substantial. Rather than a
general increase in that kind of activity, what is called for in the matter of
science funding is precisely the opposite: Ambitious projects should be funded,
if they are to be funded, fully, with a one-time vote, parking the money with
the National Science Foundation or another institution rather than
drip-dropping them through annual appropriations. These are big projects, but not
particularly big projects by Washington standards: The Large Hadron Collider
cost less than $7 billion to build, and the SSC was budgeted for around $2
billion, compared to nearly $800 billion a year for Social Security. We spend
$30 billion a year on farm subsidies, and Big Science is a better investment
than Big Elmer — Archer Daniels Midland can pay its own bills.
Funding these projects is a responsibility that must fall
to the United States, Professor Weinberg argues, because “Europe has worse financial
problems than the United States, and the European Union Commission is now
considering the removal of large science projects from the EU budget.” But he
never considers the fact that Europe’s economic woes are in part a product of
the very policies — higher taxes, bigger government — he demands. Europe is
just a little ahead of the curve. In the closing of this same essay, he demands
“restoring higher and more progressive tax rates, especially on investment
income,” not in the service of more “special pleading for one or another
particular public good,” but for a larger public sector across the board: SEC
enforcers, police, firemen — and somebody inform the UTPCPD that he used the
horribly gender-specific “firemen” rather than “firefighters” — higher pay for
teachers, the works. He never gives any reason for expecting that to produce
better results. The problem with the SEC, for example, is not manpower or
regulatory empowerment; it’s that the SEC is the safety school of financial
careers, and it is staffed by people who are not as smart or as driven as the
people who are working to subvert them, or at least to get around them.
On the subject of teachers, he writes that we ought to
spend more in order to “make becoming a teacher an attractive career choice for
our best college graduates.” But in fact, study after study after study has
shown that public-sector workers in general — and teachers specifically — are
paid far above market wages. Considering total compensation — wages, benefits,
pension, etc. — public-school teachers earn a premium of 52 percent over
similarly skilled workers in the private sector. And though I doubt that
Professor Weinberg makes it over to the Sanchez Building very often, if he did
he might notice that it is full of dimwits: Colleges of education are
consistently filled with students having the worst SAT or ACT scores of any
department — including journalism, for Pete’s sake.
He’s also a bit of a rogue in the lying-with-numbers
department, writing: “In the past decade, the National Science Foundation has
seen the fraction of grant proposals that it can fund drop from 33 percent to
23 percent.” But the NSF budget in 2014 is about 35 percent more than it was in
2004 — so what happened over the past decade? There are many possible explanations
for Professor Weinberg’s figure: The number of applications may have gone up,
the size of grants may have gone up, etc. But what did not happen was a
reduction in the NDF’s budget, and it is intellectually dishonest to imply
otherwise.
And more generally: Why should we judge the NSF’s value
by the number of projects it funds? Perhaps it would be better if it funded
fewer but better projects — the agency’s $7.6 billion budget could build a
Large Hadron Collider every year. Considering what the NSF does spend money on
— e.g., ridiculous “citizen technology forums” in which scientifically
illiterate Americans are gathered so that their views on subjects they know
nothing about can be properly assessed — fewer but better might be the right
model. Spotlight-loving congressmen like to point out ridiculous-sounding NSF
studies such as “Sexual Conflict, Social Behavior and the Evolution of
Waterfowl Genitalia,” and everybody loves a good goose-penis joke, but the real
point is that that kind of small-ball work is precisely the sort of thing that
you don’t need the nation-state corporately involved in. Even a modest
university can afford its own waterfowl-genital research, and if you want to
know what ignorant people think about science, you can stroll down to the local
college of education, where you can find people who are ignorant about any
subject you might care to identify.
But in Professor Weinberg’s world, this doesn’t matter:
We can afford categorical expansion of the public sector because “dollar for
dollar, government spending stimulates the economy more than tax cuts.” I
should note that he does preface that with “I am not an economist.” In fact,
it’s not known that “government spending” categorically stimulates the economy
at all; it seems to matter rather a lot what government spends the money on,
what sorts of institutions it acts through, economic conditions exogenous to
policy, etc. Likewise, he argues that astronomy, like physics, “faces tasks
beyond the resources of individuals,” but at the same time argues that the only
valuable science associated with the International Space Station could have
been done more easily and less expensively with an unmanned satellite —
precisely the sort of thing that private firms now do. Most Big Science projects
do not have obvious or immediate commercial applications, but then those
applications are not always predictable: The World Wide Web was invented at
CERN to help its scientists communicate with their colleagues around the world.
(And it turned out that that technology was great for porn, gambling, and cat
pictures, too.) A bigger public sector — especially one funded by higher taxes
on investment — bleeds resources out of potentially productive sources of
commercial funding for scientific research. There are a great many examples of
the fruitful interaction of public and commercial development. Unless you have
an ideological aversion to profit-oriented research, then you want to fire both
barrels.
Alternatives to the historical model are of no obvious interest
to Professor Weinberg. Reform of the NSF and other institutions? Not on his
radar: Just turn on the money hose, because it also apparently has never
occurred to him to reconsider entrusting the very institutions that made the
wrong choices with the Super Collider and the International Space Station and
so much more with more resources to make more decisions based on the same
flawed decision-making processes and subject to the same perverse political
incentives.
How smart do you have to be to argue for something that
dumb?
It is striking that a mind that has helped to unveil both
the largest and tiniest phenomena is capable of producing this catalogue of
simpleminded banalities on the relatively trivial subject of public policy.
Professor Weinberg’s limited point about Big Science is a good one; his
generalizing it into a brief for a categorically larger welfare state and
public sector is the sort of thing that should embarrass an intellectual of his
standing. And that this appeared in The Best American Science and Nature
Writing should embarrass us all, if this is the best we can do.
No comments:
Post a Comment