By Michael Barone
Tuesday, April 29, 2014
French economist Thomas Piketty’s book Capital in the
Twenty-First Century has been inspiring a lot of comment and controversy. The
English translation published last month zipped to No. 1 on Amazon.com.
It has given a lift to economists on the left who have
cheered on Barack Obama’s flagging attempts to make income inequality a voting
issue. They have hailed it as “truly superb” and “extraordinarily important.”
Others, not all on the right, have taken a jaundiced
view. “All wrong” was the verdict of one critic. “The main argument is based on
two (false) claims,” concluded another.
Piketty’s title echoes Karl Marx’s Das Kapital, and his
argument is similar: Returns on capital tend to exceed returns to labor, producing
increasing income inequality and concentration of wealth. That happened in the
19th century, he says, and is likely to happen again in the 21st. The 20th
century was a happy exception because of the wealth-destroying effects of two
world wars and the Great Depression. Piketty goes far beyond Obama’s tepid
responses (a higher minimum wage, forgiveness of college loans) to a red-hot
remedy: a global tax on wealth.
That’s obviously not going to happen any time soon. But
from the hosannas and harrumphs that have greeted the book — no, I haven’t read
all 577 pages — certain conclusions can be drawn. There is general agreement
that Piketty has compiled an impressive array of data on income inequality in
multiple nations going back 200 years or more. There is agreement also that he
thoughtfully states caveats and cautions about data interpretation. His thesis
seems at least plausible at a time when the very top incomes have increased
much more rapidly than those at the middle and bottom. Even some critics acknowledge
that, as the Washington Post’s Robert Samuelson writes: “the present
concentration of income and wealth feels excessive. It understandably stirs
resentment.”
But is his picture of current trends complete? The
Manhattan Institute’s Scott Winship points out that relying, as Piketty does,
on tax returns for the U.S. statistics means omitting income from Social
Security, food stamps, public housing, Medicare, and Medicaid. Tax returns
count roommates and unmarried partners as separate units when they are part of
a larger household. They don’t include employer-paid health insurance — an
increasing share of employee compensation in recent decades. Including these
factors, Winship notes, means that incomes below the top 10 percent have not
stagnated but have risen significantly since the 1970s. Increasing inequality
is compatible with increases in ordinary people’s incomes.
Economist Tyler Cowen takes issue with another of
Piketty’s assumptions, that the rich can earn 4 to 5 percent on their wealth
“automatically, with the mere passage of time, rather than as the result of
strategic risk-taking.” The French economist, Cowen says, has “a notion of
capital as a growing, homogeneous blob” when in fact “sudden reversals and
retrenchments are inevitable.”
Piketty concedes this is true for people with ordinary
incomes. He opposes personal investment accounts in Social Security because
there is too much risk of making bad investments. His assumption that wealthy
investors face no similar risks may have seemed plausible in the generation
after World War II, when the Fortune 500 list of major companies remained
remarkably stable. But it has made little sense in recent years, when General
Motors has gone bankrupt and Google, founded in 1998, is one of the world’s
most highly valued companies.
“There’s a persistent tension,” writes Bloomberg’s Clive
Crook, “between the limits of the data [Piketty] presents and the grandiosity
of the conclusions he draws.” Like global-warming alarmists, he extrapolates
from abstract theory and a few years’ trendlines out a century forward — and
presents the results as inevitable. He also presents them as justifying the
confiscation, more or less, of wealth accumulated by private individuals and
putting it in the hands of mandarins guided by their supposedly superior
sensitivity to public welfare. There might be less inequality in such a world,
but also less economic growth and a lower, though more equal, standard of
living.
“In perhaps the most revealing line of the book,” Cowen
writes, “the 42-year-old Piketty writes that since the age of 25, he has not
left Paris, ‘except for brief trips.’” France, where a cozy elite runs
government and large corporations, has a 75 percent top-income-tax rate and
essentially zero economic growth. Is that the future American liberals want?
No comments:
Post a Comment