By Charles Hughes
Wednesday, May 16, 2018
Note: The following piece originally appeared at e21.
Senator Bernie Sanders (I., Vt.) will soon announce his
jobs-guarantee proposal. A host of potential 2020 Democratic nominees, such as
Senators Cory Booker (D., N.J.), Elizabeth Warren (D., Mass.), and Kamala
Harris (D., Calif.), have introduced a separate pilot proposal, which would
establish a jobs-guarantee program in 15 high-unemployment areas in the country
for three years. Everyone who applied would be guaranteed a job.
While these proposals differ in scale and specifics, the
jobs would eventually pay $15 an hour, in addition to other benefits, such as
health care and paid leave. I recently wrote a column
on the difficulties of matching participants with infrastructure jobs due to
lengthy review and permitting times, but individual participants would also
face dimmer prospects in the long run.
The generosity of the compensation package offered
through the proposals would encourage some people who could have otherwise had
low-wage jobs in the private sector to shift over. If the economy were to enter
a recession, millions of unemployed might flock to jobs guaranteed by the
federal government.
In the short term, these benefits and wages would be a
boon to many of these participants. One of the major concerns is how people
would fare while in these guaranteed jobs and whether they would ever be able
to move out of the program to better employment in the private sector. In a
recent meta-analysis, economists David Card of the University of Berkeley,
Jochen Kluve of Humboldt University, and Andrea Weber of the University of
Mannheim analyzed estimates of over 200 evaluations of active labor-market
programs around the world. They found that while job-search assistance,
sanctions, or subsidized private-sector-employment programs demonstrate some
level of effectiveness, public-sector-employment subsidies generally have
negligible or even negative effects across all time horizons.
The authors note that the poor performance of
public-employment programs confirms their own earlier work and another study
from University of Chicago professor James Heckman. They suggest that the
consistently weak performance of public-jobs programs suggests that “private
employers place little value on the experiences gained in a public sector
program . . . and [programs] only serve to slow down the transition of
participants to unsubsidized jobs.”
This could be due to a range of reasons. First, private
employers might be skeptical that the work people are doing in
public-employment programs helps them develop skills or abilities that would
translate to the private sector.
Second, the need for a worker to sign up for the program
sends a negative signal about the employee’s skills. If only workers with
limited skills or prospects end up in the program, employers assume that
participants were unable to find private employment on their own and would not
be good candidates.
Third, employers might find it difficult to identify
people who performed their jobs well while in the jobs-guarantee program. As I
have written previously, the current system for evaluation of federal employees
leaves much to be desired.
Out of the almost 1.2 million permanent federal employees
included in an analysis by the Government Accountability Office, only one-tenth
of 1 percent had a performance rated “unacceptable,” and another three tenths
of 1 percent were rated “minimally successful.” More than a third of these
employees were rated “outstanding.” If performance reviews in the program are
similar to the existing efforts for current employees, they will give minimally
useful feedback to employees and impart no information to private-sector
employers.
Some participants might have been chronically absent
during their time in the program or had lackluster performance. The early draft
of the Sanders proposal suggests that a Division of Progress Investigation
would have the authority to discipline participants as needed. The track record
of disciplinary measures for current government employees should make us
extremely skeptical regarding its effectiveness. For these reasons, private
companies might then be deterred from hiring people who participated in the
jobs-guarantee program.
Aside from the problems related to cost or finding enough
timely work for jobs-guarantee participants, the program would also introduce
serious concerns about the effects on the long-term prospects for participants.
Previous research has found that public-sector-employment programs teach few
skills, leading to minimal or negative effects for employees. Once people enter
the program, they might never be able to find a way to leave, and the rolls of
participants would grow inexorably year after year.
No comments:
Post a Comment