By Kevin D. Williamson
Friday, June 23, 2017
If you’re wondering what in Hell is actually going on
with U.S. health-care policy, the short version is this: Policymakers in both
parties are trying to replicate Swiss policies in a country that isn’t Swiss.
The Affordable Care Act was, as thinkers as different as
Paul Krugman and Avik Roy both observed, an attempt to Swiss up the U.S.
health-insurance and health-care markets. (Obligatory reiteration: Those are not the same thing.) The Swiss system,
Santésuisse, achieves one big progressive goal — universal health-insurance
coverage — while offering much to please conservatives: a private market for
health insurance and health care, consumer choice, and relatively low
government spending on health care.
Santésuisse is, in its broadest strokes, a lot like the
model established by the so-called Affordable Care Act — a model that is kept
in large part by the Republicans’ “repeal-and-replace” proposal, which neither
repeals nor replaces the Affordable Care Act, though it does make some
substantial changes to it. Like Obamacare, Santésuisse mandates that all
citizens purchase insurance from private insurance companies; establishes by
law a minimum package of acceptable benefits to satisfy that mandate;
subsidizes health-insurance premiums for lower-income people, with a goal of
keeping their insurance premiums to less than 10 percent of their incomes;
mandates coverage of preexisting conditions and imposes “community rating,”
which means that low-risk insurance buyers pay higher premiums to allow for high-risk
buyers to pay lower premiums, though the Swiss do make some adjustments for age
and sex (!); it imposes controls on procedure costs and reimbursement for
providers. The Swiss model also does a few things that ACA does not: It
requires that insurance companies offer their minimal policies on a nonprofit
basis; it is structured around relatively high out-of-pocket expenses (high
copays and deductibles) in order to encourage consumers to spend soberly; and,
perhaps most important, it does this in the context of a health-insurance
market that is entirely individual: There are no employer-based
health-insurance plans in Switzerland. Everybody buys his own health insurance,
the same way people buy everything from tacos to mobile-phone service. Swiss
regulations also mandate that prices be made public, which helps consumer
markets to function.
In terms of government spending on health care,
Switzerland isn’t terribly different from the United States. Indeed, with the
exception of high-spending Norway, per-capita government spending on health
care is pretty consistent across a selection of advanced countries with very
different health-care systems: Switzerland, the United States, the Netherlands,
Sweden, Germany, and Denmark all have similar per-capita outlays.
Interestingly, none of those countries has a national single-payer system:
Sweden and Denmark have largely public systems, but they are run mostly by
local governments rather than by the national government. Among countries with
single-payer systems, there is a fair amount of variability in per-capita
spending: Australia, for example, has lower government spending than does the
United Kingdom.
In terms of total spending — government and private
spending together — countries with quite different systems lead the pack: The
United States spends the most, followed by Switzerland, Norway, the
Netherlands, Germany, Sweden, Ireland, Austria, Denmark, Belgium, and Canada.
(These are OCED statistics from 2014.) The lack of a robust relationship
between health-care systems, health-care expenses, and health-care outcomes
suggests that the most powerful determinants of these are exogenous to policy,
things like national demographic characteristics and economic conditions: Older
people with lots of disposable income will tend to spend more on medical
services, the Swedes and Okinawans have been healthy and long-lived under a
number of different health-care systems, etc.
Which is to say, one of the reasons the Swiss and the
Americans spend relatively large sums on health care may be the structure of
the insurance markets; it might simply be that they are rich countries in which
consumers choose to consume more health care, which would explain why Sweden
and Canada are in the club of relatively big spenders. And low medical spending
is not necessarily a sign of health: They don’t spend very much on health care
in Cameroon.
As Avik Roy and others have pointed out, trying to build
Swiss health-care architecture on American foundations is a project by no means
guaranteed to succeed. Switzerland, for example, has enjoyed very strong
compliance with its national health-insurance mandate. Part of that is cultural
(the Swiss are rule-following people), and part of it is that Swiss government:
If you fail to comply with the mandate, the Swiss government will garnishee
your wages and charge you a penalty equivalent to the cost of the premiums plus
up to 50 percent, and, if you persist, the government will sign you up for an
insurance policy and allow the provider to sue you for back premiums covering
the period during which you were uninsured. The American version is a little
less robust, to say the least: The ACA mandate is “enforced” with a very small
penalty that in most cases is nowhere near as expensive as signing up for
insurance. That is, the Swiss have a system under which compliance makes
economic sense, and we have a system under which non-compliance makes economic
sense.
The Affordable Care Act was designed in a dishonest way,
front-loading the revenue and backing in the expenses in order to get a nice
budget score from the Congressional Budget Office. The CBO rolled its
institutional eyes at this, and its report suggested very strongly that its
analysts did not believe a word of what they were writing, inasmuch as the most
popular parts of ACA were likely to be enforced while the unpopular bits — like
the “Cadillac tax” — would be put off or softened, resulting in a program that
in reality cost much more and produced less revenue than it did in the model
version that CBO scored. Sure enough, Hillary Rodham Clinton and Bernie Sanders
both campaigned against the Cadillac tax (it hits their union foot soldiers
first and hardest) while the House and Senate Republican plans would keep in,
in theory, but put off collecting it until 2025 — at which point the smart
money would be on its being put off again.
If you want a Swiss health-care system, then you have to
be willing to accept ruthlessly efficient Swiss enforcement and an
unsentimental Swiss bottom-line view of the program. Neither party is
interested in that: The new Republican health-care plan would formally do away
with the individual mandate while keeping a form of the preexisting-coverage
rule, which is, the protestations of the bill’s drafters notwithstanding,
probably going to be unworkable. As long as you have a mandate that insurance
companies cover preexisting conditions (i.e., that they place bets against
events that already have happened)
then you really have to have the mandate that people buy insurance, too;
otherwise you create incentives to forgo buying insurance until you are
actually sick, creating insurance markets composed mostly of sick people, a
model that is not economically sustainable. If you want to cover preexisting
conditions, then you have to have a mandate and enforce it strongly —
Switzerland’s compliance rate is about 99.5 percent. For comparison, the United
States mandates that drivers carry automotive insurance, and about one in five
drivers fails to comply with that mandate.
And while the enforcement is tougher, the subsidies are
less generous. Two-thirds of the Swiss receive no health-insurance subsidies at
all, and the subsidies that are received tend to be relatively small except for
the very poor.
But what is most critical may be that the Swiss model is
free of one big problem that most Americans do not see as a problem at all: employer-based
health-insurance programs. The Swiss market is an individual market, but most
insured Americans get their insurance from their employers. Doing away with
that would provide real benefits, but it would also bring a great deal of stress
to risk-averse Americans who are, in large part, satisfied with their
employer-based insurance plans.
A Swiss system in the United States might — might — be a
good idea, or at least better than the status quo ante of 2009. A Swiss system
with no real enforcement, sloppy economic thinking, and no dynamic,
consumer-driven insurance market? A Swiss system that replaces Swiss efficiency
with American sentimentality? It didn’t work when it was called Obamacare. It
won’t work when it’s called Trumpcare or Ryancare or McConnellcare, either.
No comments:
Post a Comment