By Kevin D. Williamson
Wednesday, August 19, 2015
A great deal of Donald Trump’s silly and illiterate trade
talk presupposes the gutting or repeal of NAFTA, the trade accord between the
United States, Canada, and Mexico that went into effect in 1994, with his
dreams of punitive sanctions and blockades. Indeed, NAFTA is a favorite
whipping boy for populists Left and Right, a reminder that populist
conservatives have much more in common with populist progressives such as
Senator Bernie Sanders than they do with the political tendency that connects
Adam Smith to F. A. Hayek and Ronald Reagan.
Trump fancies himself an ace negotiator, a skill that he
has had some chance to hone in an embarrassing series of corporate
bankruptcies, and he proposes to employ those skills to ensure trade that is
“fair” by whatever ethical standards occur to this particular serial
adulterer/crony capitalist/pathological liar/reality-television grotesque.
While Trump himself is fundamentally unserious, the Right has witnessed a
destructive reemergence of the old anti-trade populism articulated by Pat
Buchanan and Ross Perot.
Perot was the Trump of the 1990s, a billionaire
businessman with an absurdly high estimate of his own importance, though Perot
at least had the distinction of having made his own fortune. It was Perot who
famously warned of the “giant sucking sound” that would accompany U.S. capital
shifting south if NAFTA were to pass. And as many election scholars figure it,
it was also Perot who ensured the election of Bill Clinton, a previously
obscure political figure if a gifted campaigner. Another billionaire megalomaniac
ensuring the election of another Clinton would be almost pleasing in its
symmetry if it weren’t for the fact that it would do tremendous damage to the
country and the world.
Trade is one of those issues about which the strength of
people’s opinions tends to be the converse of their level of knowledge. With
that in mind, it is worth revisiting a few facts.
U.S. manufacturing has not been undermined by NAFTA. In
real (inflation-adjusted) terms, U.S. manufacturing output today is about 68
percent higher than it was before NAFTA came into effect. Real manufacturing
output today is nearly twice what it was in 1987, when NAFTA’s predecessor, the
Canada–U.S. Free Trade Agreement, was negotiated. Manufacturing output per
man-hour has skyrocketed as investments in information technology and
automation pay off, which is the main reason a smaller share of the work force
is employed in manufacturing even as output continues its steady climb. Fewer
people work in our factories today because we’ve gotten better at running them.
The United States does run large trade deficits, though
the cause and consequence of these is generally misunderstood. (Daniel
Griswold’s 1998 analysis, though inevitably dated, remains an excellent
primer.) For many years, nearly half of our trade deficit came from imports of
a single product: oil, not Hondas or cheap flip-flops from China. Oil accounted
for 40.5 percent of the trade deficit from 2000 to 2012. Thanks to fracking,
the United States is today a very substantial petroleum producer, but federal
law prohibits most crude-oil exports. A recently negotiated swap of U.S. light
crude for Mexican heavy crude required presidential dispensation, which gives
an indication of how unfree that market is. What that means is that one-way
trade in the commodity that has been an important driver of our trade deficit
is not the result of protectionist policies abroad but of protectionist
policies at home, a federal ban on oil exports enacted in 1975 to keep our
precious fluids out of the hands of wily foreigners.
In fact, there isn’t a great deal of evidence that trade
restrictions enacted by foreign countries have a great deal of long-term effect
on American producers. Annual U.S. exports have been setting new records for
years, and did so again in 2014. The largest share of U.S. exports go to Canada
and Mexico, respectively, with the third-largest market for U.S. exports being
China. China consumes about twice as much in U.S. exports as does our
next-largest overseas market, Japan, and far more than any other country down
the list. The United States runs trade surpluses with relatively protectionist
countries such as Brazil.
What drives bilateral trade deficits between the United
States and other countries is not, for the most part, trade policy, but simple
supply and demand. The United States exports a lot of farm commodities and
industrial products, along with a great deal of very high-end goods. The
effects of that are mainly psychological: We see a lot of goods on the shelves
marked “Made in China” but few overseas goods marked “Made in the USA,” because
what the United States exports isn’t consumer goods, for the most part. But you’ll
find American robotics in German automobile factories and American cotton in
Vietnamese textile plants.
Because of our size (we sometimes forget that we’re the
third-most-populous country on Earth and account for 22 percent of the planet’s
economy), we tend to run relatively large trade deficits or surpluses as a
share of trade with smaller countries, big deficits with Saudi Arabia, and big
surpluses with the Netherlands. And we tend to do lots of business with our immediate
neighbors and with other large and diverse economies. Among that group, we
generally send more exports to richer countries and fewer exports to poorer
countries, for the obvious reason that poor people are “undercapitalized” when
it comes to buying $50,000 Ford pickup trucks or Boeing jets. The poorer
countries do buy a lot of U.S.-produced food: At $152 billion a year, our
annual farm exports slightly exceed our automobile imports. And about $30
billion of those farm exports go to China; Beijing may try to game trading
terms, but hungry people are hungry people.
For the same reason that the United States tends to excel
in high-value exports, foreign companies have often found it amenable to make
some high-end goods for the American market, and other markets, in the United
States. That is not because we have protectionist policies encouraging that,
but because it saves on shipping costs and because we have a highly skilled
work force. There aren’t any Chinese companies making $1 plastic water-guns to
sell at Wal-Mart in the United States, but Mercedes-Benz makes automobiles here
and Leica makes high-end optics here (not the famous cameras, but rifle scopes
— know your market!), and not because American labor is cheap. Indeed, the
race-to-the-bottom analysis is deeply flawed; with the notable exception of
China, where wages have steadily climbed but are relatively low, global
investment tends to be concentrated on high-wage countries such as the United
States, the United Kingdom, Canada, and the countries of Western Europe. The
next time somebody tries to sell you a race-to-the-bottom story, ask why they
don’t make the BMW 7-Series in Haiti.
Conversely, because Ford sells the Focus all over the
world (it sells twice as many in China as it does in the United States), it has
made them in places as different as Michigan, Portugal, Germany, and the
Philippines.
Mexico has made great strides in automobile manufacturing
— but not because it has pursued a protectionist agenda. The opposite is the
case: While the United States pursues the occasional free-trade deal in its
sluggish and desultory fashion, Mexico has closed some 45 free-trade accords
over the past few decades, which means that builders in Mexico can export
duty-free to virtually any significant market in the world except China.
Meanwhile, the United States languishes: By most estimates, the United States
has a trade environment inferior to Sweden’s, and it has a higher corporate tax
rate than Sweden does, too.
NAFTA has had a modest positive impact on the United
States economy: positive in that it has increased both output and employment in
the United States, modest because there already was a great deal of North
American trade absent NAFTA. The treaty is not without its defects. My
colleague Jonah Goldberg has written that an ideal free-trade treaty would be
one sentence long: “There shall be free trade between . . . ” But NAFTA, like
our other trade accords, is more Rube Goldberg than Jonah Goldberg, an overly complex
piece of political machinery. But it has, despite its defects, lowered trade
barriers, to the benefit of all three parties.
It is very likely that the Trans-Pacific Partnership,
which gives so many of our talk-radio friends the willies, will do the same.
Some conservatives despise TPP because of the fast-track trade-negotiation
authority that has accompanied it — any delegation to the president is
tantamount to treason in their view — while others, mainly on the left but some
on the right, abominate its intellectual-property standards and other
provisions. The analysis that sees TPP as giving the president leverage against
Congress is so narrow as to be blind. The real advantage of negotiating a trade
deal that requires consensus among such countries as Singapore and Australia is
that these countries generally have economic policies that are superior to our
own and better suited to the realities of 21st-century markets and economic
conditions. Which is to say, it’s an opportunity to leverage Tony Abbott and
the ghost of Lee Kuan Yew against Barack Obama on the matter of free markets —
a desirable situation for conservatives.
Don’t expect to hear any of that from Donald Trump, who
imagines that the global economy is a poker game and is transfixed by the
phantasm of the inscrutable Oriental dealing from the bottom of the deck while
the sneaky Latin sharpens his machete.
No comments:
Post a Comment