By Kevin D. Williamson
Wednesday, October 07, 2020
There are many numbers that do not look very good for
Donald Trump’s reelection hopes: The most recent polls have Joe Biden leading
him by a large margin nationally and, more important, leading him in Florida,
Pennsylvania, Michigan, Wisconsin, and Arizona; Trump’s approval/disapproval
ratio is upside-down at 45/54, at least in part because 210,000 and counting
Americans have died of the coronavirus epidemic while the president gives the
impression of not taking it sufficiently seriously or of even being able to do
so; there will be about 5 million fewer Americans employed on Election Day than
on Trump’s first day in office; the number of pesos the government of Andrés
Manuel López Obrador has expended paying for a wall along the U.S.-Mexico
border is . . . 0.00.
But the number that may hurt the most is the one that
matters least: the trade deficit.
The U.S. trade deficit in goods hit an all-time high in
August. The big gains in exports to China that were supposed to have
materialized after the much-ballyhooed (by Trump, anyway) trade armistice have
failed to appear, and Americans’ appetite for imports remains as high as ever,
resulting in a trade “deficit” — the term is misleading — of $83.9 billion in
August. The overall trade deficit, which includes services as well as goods,
was lower than the goods deficit, because Americans export a lot of high-value
products classified as services. But even at the somewhat-lower figure of $67.1
billion, the overall trade deficit for August was the third-highest on record,
and — this part will sting — higher than it was at any point during the
presidency of Barack Obama.
The so-called trade deficit has always been the wrong
thing to worry about and the wrong metric of success or failure, but it is the
one Trump chose for himself, and, in that respect, he must be counted as a
failure. This is not a surprise, in that the president himself seems to
understand almost nothing at all about the issue and has chosen to surround
himself with crackpots such as Peter Navarro. His big talk about trade wars’
being “great” and “easy to win” has been accompanied by a policy of consistent incompetence,
one that has done serious damage to American businesspeople from soybean
farmers to beer
brewers. His tariffs disrupted trading relationships and supply chains, and
those disruptions did not magically disappear when the tariffs were lifted. Trade
is not an electric light that can be switched on and off at will.
The trade deficit is not a deficit in any meaningful
sense of the word; unlike the federal budget deficit, it does not contribute to
a mounting debt that Americans individually or collectively owe to somebody. If
a lawyer buys a $5 loaf of bread from your grocer, and the grocer does no
business at all with the lawyer, then he has a $5 trade deficit with the grocer
— but he doesn’t owe them $5, because the transaction already has been completed.
He does not end up $5 in debt, because his income is a heck of a lot more than
$5.
Similarly, a trade “deficit” just means that the 330
million people of the United States buy more goods and services from the 8.5
million people of Switzerland than the 8.5 million people of Switzerland buy
from the 330 million people of the United States. These relationships are
complex, and each is different from the others: Switzerland is not among the
100 most populous countries in the world, but it is a very rich one, and so it
is the 18th-largest market for U.S. exports and the 14th-largest provider of
U.S. imports; the Swiss buy a lot of gold and silver from American mines to
keep their vaults full — Switzerland is the No. 1 foreign trading partner of
Nevada — and they sell us a lot of cheese and nice watches and medical
machinery. Each country sells the other billions of dollars in pharmaceuticals.
In 2018, U.S. consumers bought about $19 billion more from Swiss producers than
Swiss consumers bought from U.S. producers. This does not hurt American
businesses or American workers in any meaningful way (except to the extent that
every seller would be happier with no competition), and it is very good for
American consumers.
The total U.S. trade deficit for 2019 — including
everything from our relatively small deficit with Switzerland to our relatively
large deficit with China to our rarely mentioned trade surpluses with
Brazil and the United Kingdom — added up to about 2.8 percent of GDP. That’s
not nothing, but it is not a problem, either. It’s just a thing.
What causes trade deficits or trade surpluses?
President Trump and many of the so-called nationalists
who share his enthusiasm for tariffs and the like believe that the cause of our
trade deficits is scheming foreigners. Scheming foreigners are a perennial
favorite target of populists right and left, from Donald Trump to Bernie
Sanders, who broadly shares Trump’s views on trade and who was, until the
day before yesterday, every inch the immigration hawk that the president is.
But trade policy is only one factor shaping these
relationships, and, in many cases, it is not the most important one. Countries
such as Japan and Singapore import the majority of their food not because wily
foreigners have tricked them into doing so but because they lack the means to
grow it themselves. Russia imports a great many automobiles because even
Russians don’t want to drive Russian cars. (One of the most significant
anti-government protests in Russia in recent years was in reaction to restrictions
on importing Japanese cars. They took to the streets in Vladivostok, and
spooked the Kremlin but good.) The United States, Mexico, and Canada have rich
and complex trade relationships mostly because they have been thrown together
by history and geography. Labor is very expensive in Switzerland, but they
aren’t making any Rolexes in Port au Prince. Governments do not have infinite
influence over what is produced or consumed within their borders, and
attempting to accumulate that kind of power is how you make a North Korea or a
Venezuela.
Japanese drivers do not buy a lot of American cars. That
is partly a matter of trade barriers (not so much tariffs as complex and
cumbrous dealership and distribution rules) but also in no small part a result
of the fact that Japanese people do not like American cars very much. Like
millions of middle-class Americans, millions of middle-class Japanese prefer
Japanese cars; and, like millions of rich Americans, millions of rich Japanese
prefer European cars. They love Buicks in Beijing, but not in Tokyo. People
like what they like.
But what is in most cases more important than consumer
behavior is investor behavior. Americans have a relatively low rate of
savings, and the Chinese have a relatively high rate of savings. (Neither one
of these is necessarily an obviously better stance than the other, though I
will admit a prejudice in favor of higher savings rates.) Savers are investors.
A Chinese businessman who earns $1 from selling a crate of flipflops to Walmart
has some choices about what to do with that dollar. He could use it to buy $1
worth of goods from a U.S. buyer. He could trade it for £0.77, if he wants to
buy something from a British seller who only takes British currency. Or,
instead of spending it, he could save it and invest it — and the world loves to
invest in the United States. A foreigner with $1 in his pocket can buy $1 in
consumer goods or invest $1 in assets, and every dollar invested in assets is a
dollar not available for consumer-goods purchases.
Trade deficits are capital inflows. As David
Kreutzer puts it in his very forthrightly titled “The Uselessness of Trade
Deficits in Calculating Economic Vitality”:
International trade is always
balanced. Trade deficits are imbalances in only a single part of the total
balance of international payments. Any trade deficit is offset by surpluses in
other parts of the balance of payments. These offsetting surpluses in the
financial account provide an economic stimulus at least as important as that
from exports of goods and services. A trade deficit means that the home country
receives goods and services with a greater total value than the value of the
home country’s exports. However, this trade deficit is matched by an
identically sized surplus in inflow of foreign investment into the home
country. . . . Trade deficits are not a measure of lost income or jobs; trade
surpluses are not necessarily good things nor signs that a nation is “winning”
a competition.
Far from being a sign of economic trouble, U.S. trade
deficits tend to grow a little bit when the economy is doing especially well,
because a booming economy means that Americans have more money to spend, and
they spend some of that money on Japanese electronics and German cars. The fact
that our trade deficit is growing right now does not tell us very much about
the overall economic health of the country, but it is another piece of evidence
that the economy is, in fact, doing a little bit better than many economists
had expected. The fact that Americans are spending on imports is probably a
good sign, and the opposite would be a concerning development.
Of course, Trump doesn’t have the good sense to make that
point, and Larry Kudlow, alas, is not the president of the United States. So
Trump must be judged on his own terms — building the wall, shrinking the trade
deficit — and found wanting.
No comments:
Post a Comment